homework

 Write a 2 – page response (APA 7, double-space) to scientific management. (~600 words) 

Save Time On Research and Writing
Hire a Pro to Write You a 100% Plagiarism-Free Paper.
Get My Paper

Introduction

THE PRINCIPLES OF SCIENTIFIC MANAGEMENT

by Frederick W. Taylor

Save Time On Research and Writing
Hire a Pro to Write You a 100% Plagiarism-Free Paper.
Get My Paper

Introduction
Chapter 1:
Fundamentals of
Scientific Management
Chapter 2:
The Principles of
Scientific Management

Introduction

President Roosevelt in his address to the Governors at the
White House, prophetically remarked that “The conservation
of our national resources is only preliminary to the larger
question of national efficiency.”

The whole country at once recognized the importance of
conserving our material resources and a large movement
has been started which will be effective in accomplishing
this object. As yet, however, we have but vaguely
appreciated the importance of “the larger question of
increasing our national efficiency.”

We can see our forests vanishing, our water-powers going
to waste, our soil being carried by floods into the sea; and
the end of our coal and our iron is in sight. But our larger
wastes of human effort, which go on every day through
such of our acts as are blundering, ill-directed, or inefficient,
and which Mr. Roosevelt refers to as a, lack of “national
efficiency,” are less visible, less tangible, and are but
vaguely appreciated.

We can see and feel the waste of material things. Awkward,
inefficient, or ill-directed movements of men, however,
leave nothing visible or tangible behind them. Their
appreciation calls for an act of memory, an effort of the
imagination. And for this reason, even though our daily loss
from this source is greater than from our waste of material
things, the one has stirred us deeply, while the other has
moved us but little.

As yet there has been no public agitation for “greater
national efficiency,” no meetings have been called to
consider how this is to be brought about. And still there are
signs that the need for greater efficiency is widely felt.

The search for better, for more competent men, from the
presidents of our great companies down to our household
servants, was never more vigorous than it is now. And more
than ever before is the demand for competent men in
excess of the supply.

What we are all looking for, however, is the readymade,
competent man; the man whom some one else has trained.
It is only when we fully realize that our duty, as well as our
opportunity, lies in systematically cooperating to train and
to make this competent man, instead of in hunting for a
man whom some one else has trained, that we shall be on

file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/

  • intro.htm
  • (1 of 3)10/25/2006 12:28:25 PM

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/index.htm

    Introduction

    the road to national efficiency.

    In the past the prevailing idea has been well expressed in
    the saying that “Captains of industry are born, not made”;
    and the theory has been that if one could get the right man,
    methods could be safely left to him. In the future it will be
    appreciated that our leaders must be trained right as well as
    born right, and that no great man can (with the old system
    of personal management) hope to compete with a number
    of ordinary men who have been properly organized so as
    efficiently to cooperate.

    In the past the man has been first; in the future the system
    must be first. This in no sense, however, implies that great
    men are not needed. On the contrary, the first object of any
    good system must be that of developing first-class men;
    and under systematic management the best man rises to
    the top more certainly and more rapidly than ever before.

    This paper has been written:

    First. To point out, through a series of simple illustrations,
    the great loss which the whole country is suffering through
    inefficiency in almost all of our daily acts.

    Second. To try to convince the reader that the remedy for
    this inefficiency lies in systematic management, rather than
    in searching for some unusual or extraordinary man.

    Third. To prove that the best management is a true science,
    resting upon clearly defined laws, rules, and principles, as a
    foundation. And further to show that the fundamental
    principles of scientific management are applicable to all
    kinds of human activities, from our simplest individual acts
    to the work of our great corporations, which call for the
    most elaborate cooperation. And, briefly, through a series of
    illustrations, to convince the reader that whenever these
    principles are correctly applied, results must follow which
    are truly astounding.

    This paper was originally prepared for presentation to the
    American Society of Mechanical Engineers. The illustrations
    chosen are such as, it is believed, will especially appeal to
    engineers and to managers of industrial and manufacturing
    establishments, and also quite as much to all of the men
    who are working in these establishments. It is hoped,
    however, that it will be clear to other readers that the same
    principles can be applied with equal force to all social
    activities: to the management of our homes; the
    management of our farms; the management of the business
    of our tradesmen, large and small; of our churches, our
    philanthropic institutions our universities, and our
    governmental departments.

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/intro.htm (2 of 3)10/25/2006 12:28:25 PM

    Introduction

    Go to: Introduction Chapter 1 Chapter 2

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/intro.htm (3 of 3)10/25/2006 12:28:25 PM

    Chapter 1: Fundamentals of Scientific Management

    THE PRINCIPLES OF SCIENTIFIC MANAGEMENT

    by Frederick W. Taylor
    Introduction
    Chapter 1:
    Fundamentals of
    Scientific Management
    Chapter 2:
    The Principles of
    Scientific Management

    Chapter 1: Fundamentals of Scientific Management

    The principal object of management should be to secure the
    maximum prosperity for the employer, coupled with the
    maximum prosperity for each employee.

    The words “maximum prosperity” are used, in their broad
    sense, to mean not only large dividends for the company or
    owner, but the development of every branch of the business
    to its highest state of excellence, so that the prosperity may
    be permanent. In the same way maximum prosperity for
    each employee means not only higher wages than are
    usually received by men of his class, but, of more
    importance still, it also means the development of each man
    to his state of maximum efficiency, so that he may be able
    to do, generally speaking, the highest grade of work for
    which his natural abilities fit him, and it further means
    giving him, when possible, this class of work to do.

    It would seem to be so self-evident that maximum
    prosperity for the employer, coupled with maximum
    prosperity for the employee, ought to be the two leading
    objects of management, that even to state this fact should
    be unnecessary. And yet there is no question that,
    throughout the industrial world, a large part of the
    organization of employers, as well as employees, is for war
    rather than for peace, and that perhaps the majority on
    either side do not believe that it is possible so to arrange
    their mutual relations that their interests become identical.

    The majority of these men believe that the fundamental
    interests of employees and employers are necessarily
    antagonistic. Scientific management, on the contrary, has
    for its very foundation the firm conviction that the true
    interests of the two are one and the same; that prosperity
    for the employer cannot exist through a long term of years
    unless it is accompanied by prosperity for the employee,
    and vice versa; and that it is possible to give the workman
    what he most wants–high wages–and the employer what
    he wants–a low labor cost–for his manufactures.

    It is hoped that some at least of those who do not
    sympathize with each of these objects may be led to modify
    their views; that some employers, whose attitude toward
    their workmen has been that of trying to get the largest
    amount of work out of them for the smallest possible
    wages, may be led to see that a more liberal policy toward
    their men will pay them better; and that some of those
    workmen who begrudge a fair and even a large profit to

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/

  • 01.htm
  • (1 of 12)10/25/2006 12:28:31 PM

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/index.htm

    Chapter 1: Fundamentals of Scientific Management

    their employers, and who feel that all of the fruits of their
    labor should belong to them, and that those for whom they
    work and the capital invested in the business are entitled to
    little or nothing, may be led to modify these views.

    No one can be found who will deny that in the case of any
    single individual the greatest prosperity can exist only when
    that individual has reached his highest state of efficiency;
    that is, when he is turning out his largest daily output.

    The truth of this fact is also perfectly clear in the case of
    two men working together. To illustrate: if you and your
    workman have become so skilful that you and he together
    are making two pairs of, shoes in a day, while your
    competitor and his workman are making only one pair, it is
    clear that after selling your two pairs of shoes you can pay
    your workman much higher wages than your competitor
    who produces only one pair of shoes is able to pay his man,
    and that there will still be enough money left over for you to
    have a larger profit than your competitor.

    In the case of a more complicated manufacturing
    establishment, it should also be perfectly clear that the
    greatest permanent prosperity for the workman, coupled
    with the greatest prosperity for the employer, can be
    brought about only when the work of the establishment is
    done with the smallest combined expenditure of human
    effort, plus nature’s resources, plus the cost for the use of
    capital in the shape of machines, buildings, etc. Or, to state
    the same thing in a different way: that the greatest
    prosperity can exist only as the result of the greatest
    possible productivity of the men and machines of the
    establishment–that is, when each man and each machine
    are turning out the largest possible output; because unless
    your men and your machines are daily turning out more
    work than others around you, it is clear that competition will
    prevent your paying higher wages to your workmen than
    are paid to those of your competitor. And what is true as to
    the possibility of paying high wages in the case of two
    companies competing close beside one another is also true
    as to whole districts of the country and even as to nations
    which are in competition. In a word, that maximum
    prosperity can exist only as the result of maximum
    productivity. Later in this paper illustrations will be given of
    several companies which are earning large dividends and at
    the same time paying from 30 per cent to 100 per cent
    higher wages to their men than are paid to similar men
    immediately around them, and with whose employers they
    are in competition. These illustrations will cover different
    types of work, from the most elementary to the most
    complicated.

    If the above reasoning is correct, it follows that the most
    important object of both the workmen and the management
    should be the training and development of each individual in
    the establishment, so that he can do (at his fastest pace

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/01.htm (2 of 12)10/25/2006 12:28:31 PM

    Chapter 1: Fundamentals of Scientific Management

    and with the maximum of efficiency) the highest class of
    work for which his natural abilities fit him.

    These principles appear to be so self-evident that many
    men may think it almost childish to state them. Let us,
    however, turn to the facts, as they actually exist in this
    country and in England. The English and American peoples
    are the greatest sportsmen in the world. Whenever an
    American workman plays baseball, or an English workman
    plays cricket, it is safe to say that he strains every nerve to
    secure victory for his side. He does his very best to make
    the largest possible number of runs. The universal
    sentiment is so strong that any man who fails to give out all
    there is in him in sport is branded as a “quitter,” and
    treated with contempt by those who are around him.

    When the same workman returns to work on the following
    day, instead of using every effort to turn out the largest
    possible amount of work, in a majority of the cases this
    man deliberately plans to do as little as he safely can to
    turn out far less work than he is well able to do in many
    instances to do not more than one-third to one-half of a
    proper day’s work. And in fact if he were to do his best to
    turn out his largest possible day’s work, he would be abused
    by his fellow-workers for so doing, even more than if he had
    proved himself a “quitter” in sport. Under working, that is,
    deliberately working slowly so as to avoid doing a full day’s
    work, “soldiering,” as it is called in this country, “hanging it
    out,” as it is called in England, “ca canae,” as it is called in
    Scotland, is almost universal in industrial establishments,
    and prevails also to a large extent in the building trades;
    and the writer asserts without fear of contradiction that this
    constitutes the greatest evil with which the working-people
    of both England and America are now afflicted.

    It will be shown later in this paper that doing away with
    slow working and “soldiering” in all its forms and so
    arranging the relations between employer and employs that
    each workman will work to his very best advantage and at
    his best speed, accompanied by the intimate cooperation
    with the management and the help (which the workman
    should receive) from the management, would result on the
    average in nearly doubling the output of each man and each
    machine. What other reforms, among those which are being
    discussed by these two nations, could do as much toward
    promoting prosperity, toward the diminution of poverty, and
    the alleviation of suffering? America and England have been
    recently agitated over such subjects as the tariff, the control
    of the large corporations on the one hand, and of hereditary
    power on the other hand, and over various more or less
    socialistic proposals for taxation, etc. On these subjects
    both peoples have been profoundly stirred, and yet hardly a
    voice has been raised to call attention to this vastly greater
    and more important subject of “soldiering,” which directly
    and powerfully affects the wages, the prosperity, and the
    life of almost every working-man, and also quite as much

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/01.htm (3 of 12)10/25/2006 12:28:31 PM

    Chapter 1: Fundamentals of Scientific Management

    the prosperity of every industrial, establishment in the
    nation.

    The elimination of “soldiering” and of the several causes of
    slow working would so lower the cost of production that
    both our home and foreign markets would be greatly
    enlarged, and we could compete on more than even terms
    with our rivals. It would remove one of the fundamental
    causes for dull times, for lack of employment, and for
    poverty, and therefore would have a more permanent and
    far-reaching effect upon these misfortunes than any of the
    curative remedies that are now being used to soften their
    consequences. It would insure higher wages and make
    shorter working hours and better working and home
    conditions possible.

    Why is it, then, in the face of the self-evident fact that
    maximum prosperity can exist only as the result of the
    determined effort of each workman to turn out each day his
    largest possible day’s work, that the great majority of our
    men are deliberately doing just the opposite, and that even
    when the men have the best of intentions their work is in
    most cases far from efficient?

    There are three causes for this condition, which may be
    briefly summarized as:

    First. The fallacy, which has from time immemorial been
    almost universal among workmen, that a material increase
    in the output of each man or each machine in the trade
    would result in the end in throwing a large number of men
    out of work.

    Second. The defective systems of management which are in
    common use, and which make it necessary for each
    workman to soldier, or work slowly, in order that he may
    protect his own best interests.

    Third. The inefficient rule-of-thumb methods, which are still
    almost universal in all trades, and in practicing which our
    workmen waste a large part of their effort.

    This paper will attempt to show the enormous gains which
    would result from the substitution by our workmen of
    scientific for rule-of-thumb methods.

    To explain a little more fully these three causes:

    First. The great majority of workmen still believe that if they
    were to work at their best speed they would be doing a
    great injustice to the whole trade by throwing a lot of men
    out of work, and yet the history of the development of each
    trade shows that each improvement, whether it be the
    invention of a new machine or the introduction of a better
    method, which results in increasing the productive capacity

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/01.htm (4 of 12)10/25/2006 12:28:31 PM

    Chapter 1: Fundamentals of Scientific Management

    of the men in the trade and cheapening the costs, instead of
    throwing men out of work make in the end work for more
    men.

    The cheapening of any article in common use almost
    immediately results in a largely increased demand for that
    article. Take the case of shoes, for instance. The
    introduction of machinery for doing every element of the
    work which was formerly done by hand has resulted in
    making shoes at a fraction of their former labor cost, and in
    selling them so cheap that now almost every man, woman,
    and child in the working-classes buys one or two pairs of
    shoes per year, and wears shoes all the time, whereas
    formerly each workman bought perhaps one pair of shoes
    every five years, and went barefoot most of the time,
    wearing shoes only as a luxury or as a matter of the
    sternest necessity. In spite of the enormously increased
    output of shoes per workman, which has come with shoe
    machinery, the demand for shoes has so increased that
    there are relatively more men working in the shoe industry
    now than ever before.

    The workmen in almost every trade have before them an
    object lesson of this kind, and yet, because they are
    ignorant of the history of their own trade even, they still
    firmly believe, as their fathers did before them, that it is
    against their best interests for each man to turn out each
    day as much work as possible.

    Under this fallacious idea a large proportion of the workmen
    of both countries each day deliberately work slowly so as to
    curtail the output. Almost every labor union has made, or is
    contemplating making, rules which have for their object ‘
    curtailing the output of their members, and those men who
    have the greatest influence with the working-people, the
    labor leaders as well as many people with philanthropic
    feelings who are helping them, are daily spreading this
    fallacy and at the same time telling them that they are
    overworked.

    A great deal has been and is being constantly said about
    “sweat-shop” work and conditions. The writer has great
    sympathy with those who are overworked, but on the whole
    a greater sympathy for those who are under paid. For every
    individual, however, who is overworked, there are a
    hundred who intentionally under work–greatly under work–
    every day of their lives, and who for this reason deliberately
    aid in establishing those conditions which in the end
    inevitably result in low wages. And yet hardly a single voice
    is being raised in an endeavor to correct this evil.

    As engineers and managers, we are more intimately
    acquainted with these facts than any other class in the
    community, and are therefore best fitted to lead in a
    movement to combat this fallacious idea by educating not
    only the workmen but the whole of the country as to the

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/01.htm (5 of 12)10/25/2006 12:28:31 PM

    Chapter 1: Fundamentals of Scientific Management

    true facts. And yet we are practically doing nothing in this
    direction, and are leaving this field entirely in the hands of
    the labor agitators (many of whom are misinformed and
    misguided), and of sentimentalists who are ignorant as to
    actual working conditions.

    Second. As to the second cause for soldiering–the relations
    which exist between employers and employees under
    almost all of the systems of management which are in
    common use–it is impossible in a few words to make it
    clear to one not familiar with this problem why it is that the
    ignorance of employers as to the proper time in which work
    of various kinds should be done makes it for the interest of
    the workman to “soldier.”

    The writer therefore quotes herewith from a paper read
    before The American Society of Mechanical Engineers, in
    June, 1903, entitled “Shop Management,” which it is hoped
    will explain fully this cause for soldiering:

    “This loafing or soldiering proceeds from two causes. First,
    from the natural instinct and tendency of men to take it
    easy, which may be called natural soldiering. Second, from
    more intricate second thought and reasoning caused by
    their relations with other men, which may be called
    systematic soldiering.”

    “There is no question that the tendency of the average man
    (in all walks of life) is toward working at a slow, easy gait,
    and that it is only after a good deal of thought and
    observation on his part or as a result of example,
    conscience, or external pressure that he takes a more rapid
    pace.”

    “There are, of course, men of unusual energy, vitality, and
    ambition who naturally choose the fastest gait, who set up
    their own standards, and who work hard, even though it
    may be against their best interests. But these few
    uncommon men only serve by forming a contrast to
    emphasize the tendency of the average.”

    “This common tendency to ‘take it easy’ is greatly increased
    by bringing a number of men together on similar work and
    at a uniform standard rate of pay by the day.”

    “Under this plan the better men gradually but surely slow
    down their gait to that of the poorest and least efficient.
    When a naturally energetic man works for a few days beside
    a lazy one, the logic of the situation is unanswerable.”

    “Why should I work hard when that lazy fellow gets the
    same pay that I do and does only half as much work?”

    “A careful time study of men working under these conditions
    will disclose facts which are ludicrous as well as pitiable.”

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/01.htm (6 of 12)10/25/2006 12:28:31 PM

    Chapter 1: Fundamentals of Scientific Management

    “To illustrate: The writer has timed a naturally energetic
    workman who, while going and coming from work, would
    walk at a speed of from three to four miles per hour, and
    not infrequently trot home after a day’s work. On arriving at
    his work he would immediately slow down to a speed of
    about one mile an hour. When, for example, wheeling a
    loaded wheelbarrow, he would go at a good fast pace even
    up hill in order to be as short a time as possible under load,
    and immediately on the return walk slow down to a mile an
    hour, improving every opportunity for delay short of
    actually sitting down. In order to be sure not to do more
    than his lazy neighbor, he would actually tire himself in his
    effort to go slow.”

    “These men were working under a foreman of good
    reputation and highly thought of by his employer, who,
    when his attention was called to this state of things,
    answered: ‘Well, I can keep them from sitting down, but the
    devil can’t make them get a move on while they are at
    work.'”

    “The natural laziness of men is serious, but by far the
    greatest evil from which both workmen and employers are
    suffering is the systematic soldiering which is almost
    universal under all of the ordinary schemes of management
    and which results from a careful study on the part of the
    workmen of what will promote their best interests.”

    “The writer was much interested recently in hearing one
    small but experienced golf caddy boy of twelve explaining to
    a green caddy, who had shown special energy and interest,
    the necessity of going slow and lagging behind his man
    when he came up to the ball, showing him that since they
    were paid by the hour, the faster they went the less money
    they got, and finally telling him that if he went too fast the
    other boys would give him a licking.”

    “This represents a type of systematic soldiering which is
    not, however, very serious, since it is done with the
    knowledge of the employer, who can quite easily break it up
    if he wishes.”

    “The greater part of the systematic soldiering, however, is
    done by the men with the deliberate object of keeping their
    employers ignorant of how fast work can be done.”

    “So universal is soldiering for this purpose that hardly a
    competent workman can be found in a large establishment,
    whether he works by the day or on piece work, contract
    work, or under any of the ordinary systems, who does not
    devote a considerable part of his time to studying just how
    slow he can work and still convince his employer that he is
    going at a good pace.”

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/01.htm (7 of 12)10/25/2006 12:28:31 PM

    Chapter 1: Fundamentals of Scientific Management

    “The causes for this are, briefly, that practically all
    employers determine upon a maximum sum which they feel
    it is right for each of their classes of employees to earn per
    day, whether their men work by the day or piece.”

    “Each workman soon finds out about what this figure is for
    his particular case, and he also realizes that when his
    employer is convinced that a man is capable of doing more
    work than he has done, he will find sooner or later some
    way of compelling him to do it with little or no increase of
    pay.”

    “Employers derive their knowledge of how much of a given
    class of work can be done in a day from either their own
    experience, which has frequently grown hazy with age, from
    casual and unsystematic observation of their men, or at
    best from records which are kept, showing the quickest time
    in which each job has been done. In many cases the
    employer will feel almost certain that a given job can be
    done faster than it has been, but he rarely cares to take the
    drastic measures necessary to force men to do it in the
    quickest time, unless he has an actual record proving
    conclusively how fast the work can be done.”

    “It evidently becomes for each man’s interest, then, to see
    that no job is done faster than it has been in the past. The
    younger and less experienced men are taught this by their
    elders, and all possible persuasion and social pressure is
    brought to bear upon the greedy and selfish men to keep
    them from making new records which result in temporarily
    increasing their wages, while all those who come after them
    are made to work harder for the same old pay.”

    “Under the best day work of the ordinary type, when
    accurate records are kept of the amount of work done by
    each man and of his efficiency, and when each man’s wages
    are raised as he improves, and those who fail to rise to a
    certain standard are discharged and a fresh supply of
    carefully selected men are given work in their places, both
    the natural loafing and systematic soldiering can be largely
    broken up. This can only be done, however, when the men
    are thoroughly convinced that there is no intention of
    establishing piece work even in the remote future, and it is
    next to impossible to make men believe this when the work
    is of such a nature that they believe piece work to be
    practicable. In most cases their fear of making a record
    which will be used as a basis for piece work will cause them
    to soldier as much as they dare.”

    “It is, however, under piece work that the art of systematic
    soldiering is thoroughly developed; after a workman has
    had the price per piece of the work he is doing lowered two
    or three times as a result of his having worked harder and
    increased his output, he is likely entirely to lose sight of his
    employer’s side of the case and become imbued with a grim
    determination to have no more cuts if soldiering can

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/01.htm (8 of 12)10/25/2006 12:28:31 PM

    Chapter 1: Fundamentals of Scientific Management

    prevent it. Unfortunately for the character of the workman,
    soldiering involves a deliberate attempt to mislead and
    deceive his employer, and thus upright and straightforward
    workmen are compelled to become more or less
    hypocritical. The employer is soon looked upon as an
    antagonist, if not an enemy, and the mutual confidence
    which should exist between a leader and his men, the
    enthusiasm, the feeling that they are all working for the
    same end and will share in the results is entirely lacking.

    “The feeling of antagonism under the ordinary piece-work
    system becomes in many cases so marked on the part of
    the men that any proposition made by their employers,
    however reasonable, is looked upon with suspicion, and
    soldiering becomes such a fixed habit that men will
    frequently take pains to restrict the product of machines
    which they are running when even a large increase in
    output would involve no more work on their part.”

    Third. As to the third cause for slow work, considerable
    space will later in this paper be devoted to illustrating the
    great gain, both to employers and employees, which results
    from the substitution of scientific for rule-of-thumb methods
    in even the smallest details of the work of every trade. The
    enormous saving of time and therefore increase in the
    output which it is possible to effect through eliminating
    unnecessary motions and substituting fast for slow and
    inefficient motions for the men working in any of our trades
    can be fully realized only after one has personally seen the
    improvement which results from a thorough motion and
    time study, made by a competent man.

    To explain briefly: owing to the fact that the workmen in all
    of our trades have been taught the details of their work by
    observation of those immediately around them, there are
    many different ways in common use for doing the same
    thing, perhaps forty, fifty, or a hundred ways of doing each
    act in each trade, and for the same reason there is a great
    variety in the implements used for each class of work. Now,
    among the various methods and implements used in each
    element of each trade there is always one method and one
    implement which is quicker and better than any of the rest.

    And this one best method and best implement can only be
    discovered or developed through a scientific study and
    analysis of all of the methods and implements in use,
    together with accurate, minute, motion and time study. This
    involves the gradual substitution of science for rule of
    thumb throughout the mechanic arts.

    This paper will show that the underlying philosophy of all of
    the old systems of management in common use makes it
    imperative that each workman shall be left with the final
    responsibility for doing his job practically as he thinks best,
    with comparatively little help and advice from the
    management. And it will also show that because of this

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/01.htm (9 of 12)10/25/2006 12:28:31 PM

    Chapter 1: Fundamentals of Scientific Management

    isolation of workmen, it is in most cases impossible for the
    men working under these systems to do their work in
    accordance with the rules and laws of a science or art, even
    where one exists.

    The writer asserts as a general principle (and he proposes
    to give illustrations tending to prove the fact later in this
    paper) that in almost all of the mechanic arts the science
    which underlies each act of each workman is so great and
    amounts to so much that the workman who is best suited to
    actually doing the work is incapable of fully understanding
    this science, without the guidance and help of those who
    are working with him or over him, either through lack of
    education or through insufficient mental capacity. In order
    that the work may be done in accordance with scientific
    laws, it is necessary that there shall be a far more equal
    division of the responsibility between the management and
    the workmen than exists under any of the ordinary types of
    management. Those in the management whose duty it is to
    develop this science should also guide and help the
    workman in working under it, and should assume a much
    larger share of the responsibility for results than under
    usual conditions is assumed by the management.

    The body of this paper will make it clear that, to work
    according to scientific laws, the management must take
    over and perform much of the work which is now left to the
    men; almost every act of the workman should be preceded
    by one or more preparatory acts of the management which
    enable him to do his work better and quicker than he
    otherwise could. And each man should daily be taught by
    and receive the most friendly help from those who are over
    him, instead of being, at the one extreme, driven or coerced
    by his bosses, and at the other left to his own unaided
    devices.

    This close, intimate, personal cooperation between the
    management and the men is of the essence of modern
    scientific or task management.

    It will be shown by a series of practical illustrations that,
    through this friendly cooperation, namely, through sharing
    equally in every day’s burden, all of the great obstacles
    (above described) to obtaining the maximum output for
    each man and each machine in the establishment are swept
    away. The\ 30 per cent to 100 per cent increase in wages
    which the workmen are able to earn beyond what they
    receive under the old type of management, coupled with the
    daily intimate shoulder to shoulder contact with the
    management, entirely removes all cause for soldiering. And
    in a few years, under this system, the workmen have before
    them the object lesson of seeing that a great increase in the
    output per man results in giving employment to more men,
    instead of throwing men out of work, thus completely
    eradicating the fallacy that a larger output for each man will
    throw other men out of work.

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/01.htm (10 of 12)10/25/2006 12:28:31 PM

    Chapter 1: Fundamentals of Scientific Management

    It is the writer’s judgment, then, that while much can be
    done and should be done by writing and talking toward
    educating not only workmen, but all classes in the
    community, as to the importance of obtaining the maximum
    output of each man and each machine, it is only through
    the adoption of modern scientific management that this
    great problem can be finally solved. Probably most of the
    readers of this paper will say that all of this is mere theory.
    On the contrary, the theory, or philosophy, of scientific
    management is just beginning to be understood, whereas
    the management itself has been a gradual evolution,
    extending over a period of nearly thirty years. And during
    this time the employees of one company after another,
    including a large range and diversity of industries, have
    gradually changed from the ordinary to the scientific type of
    management. At least 50,000 workmen in the United States
    are now employed under this system; and they are
    receiving from 30 per cent to 100 per cent higher wages
    daily than are paid to men of similar caliber with whom they
    are surrounded, while the companies employing them are
    more prosperous than ever before. In these companies the
    output, per man and per machine, has on an average been
    doubled. During all these years there has never been a
    single strike among the men working under this system. In
    place of the suspicious watchfulness and the more or less
    open warfare which characterizes the ordinary types of
    management, there is universally friendly cooperation
    between the management and the men.

    Several papers have been written, describing the expedients
    which have been adopted and the details which have been
    developed under scientific management and the steps to be
    taken in changing from the ordinary to the scientific type.
    But unfortunately most of the readers of these papers have
    mistaken the mechanism for the true essence. Scientific
    management fundamentally consists of certain broad
    general principles, a certain philosophy, which can be
    applied in many ways, and a description of what any one
    man or men may believe to be the best mechanism for
    applying these general principles should in no way be
    confused with the principles themselves.

    It is not here claimed that any single panacea exists for all
    of the troubles of the working-people or of employers. As
    long as some people are born lazy or inefficient, and others
    are born greedy and brutal, as long as vice and crime are
    with us, just so long will a certain amount of poverty,
    misery, and unhappiness be with us Also. No system of
    management, no single expedient–within the control of any
    man or any set of men can insure continuous prosperity to
    either workmen or employers. Prosperity depends upon so
    many factors entirely beyond the control of any one set of
    men, any state, or even any one country, that certain
    periods will inevitably come when both sides must suffer,
    more or less. It is claimed, however, that under scientific
    management the intermediate periods will be far more

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/01.htm (11 of 12)10/25/2006 12:28:31 PM

    Chapter 1: Fundamentals of Scientific Management

    prosperous, far happier, and more free from discord and
    dissension. And also, that the periods will be fewer, shorter
    and the suffering less. And this will be particularly true in
    any one town, any one section of the country, or any one
    state which first substitutes the principles of scientific
    management for the rule of thumb.

    That these principles are certain to come into general use
    practically throughout the civilized world, sooner or later,
    the writer is profoundly convinced, and the sooner they
    come the better for all the people.

    Go to: Introduction Chapter 1 Chapter 2

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/01.htm (12 of 12)10/25/2006 12:28:31 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    THE PRINCIPLES OF SCIENTIFIC MANAGEMENT
    by Frederick W. Taylor
    Introduction
    Chapter 1:
    Fundamentals of
    Scientific Management
    Chapter 2:
    The Principles of
    Scientific Management

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    The writer has found that there are three questions
    uppermost in the minds of men when they become
    interested in scientific management.

    First. Wherein do the principles of scientific management
    differ essentially from those of ordinary management?

    Second. Why are better results attained under scientific
    management than under the other types?

    Third. Is not the most important problem that of getting the
    right man at the head of the company? And if you have the
    right man cannot the choice of the type of management be
    safely left to him?

    One of the principal objects of the following pages will be to
    give a satisfactory answer to these questions.

    THE FINEST TYPE OF ORDINARY MANAGEMENT

    Before starting to illustrate the principles of scientific
    management, or “task management” as it is briefly called, it
    seems desirable to outline what the writer believes will be
    recognized as the best type of management which is in
    common use. This is done So that the great difference
    between the best of the ordinary management and scientific
    management may be fully appreciated.

    In an industrial establishment which employs say from 500
    to 1000 workmen, there will be found in many cases at
    least twenty to thirty different trades. The workmen in each
    of these trades have had their knowledge handed down to
    them by word of mouth, through the many years in which
    their trade has been developed from the primitive condition,
    in which our far-distant ancestors each one practiced the
    rudiments of many different trades, to the present state of
    great and growing subdivision of labor, in which each man
    specializes upon some comparatively small class of work.

    The ingenuity of each generation has developed quicker and
    better methods for doing every element of the work in
    every trade. Thus the methods which are now in use may in
    a broad sense be said to be an evolution representing the
    survival of the fittest and best of the ideas which have been
    developed since the starting of each trade. However, while
    this is true in a broad sense, only those who are intimately

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/

  • 02.htm
  • (1 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/index.htm

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    acquainted with each of these trades are fully aware of the
    fact that in hardly any element of any trade is there
    uniformity in the methods which are used. Instead of having
    only one way which is generally accepted as a standard,
    there are in daily use, say, fifty or a hundred different ways
    of doing each element of the work. And a little thought will
    make it clear that this must inevitably be the case, since our
    methods have been handed down from man to man by word
    of mouth, or have, in most cases, been almost
    unconsciously learned through personal observation.
    Practically in no instances have they been codified or
    systematically analyzed or described. The ingenuity and
    experience of each generation–of each decade, even, have
    without doubt handed over better methods to the next. This
    mass of rule-of-thumb or traditional knowledge may be said
    to be the principal asset or possession of every tradesman.
    Now, in the best of the ordinary types of management, the
    managers recognize frankly the fact that the 500 or 1000
    workmen, included in the twenty to thirty trades, who are
    under them, possess this mass of traditional knowledge, a
    large part of which is not in the possession of the
    management. The management, of course, includes
    foremen and superintendents, who themselves have been in
    most cases first-class workers at their trades. And yet these
    foremen and superintendents know, better than any one
    else, that their own knowledge and personal skill falls far
    short of the combined knowledge and dexterity of all the
    workmen under them. The most experienced managers
    therefore frankly place before their workmen the problem of
    doing the work in the best and most economical way. They
    recognize the task before them as that of inducing each
    workman to use his best endeavors, his hardest work, all
    his traditional knowledge, his skill, his ingenuity, and his
    good-will–in a word, his “initiative,” so as to yield the
    largest possible return to his employer. The problem before
    the management, then, may be briefly said to be that of
    obtaining the best initiative of every workman. And the
    writer uses the word “initiative” in its broadest sense, to
    cover all of the good qualities sought for from the men.

    On the other hand, no intelligent manager would hope to
    obtain in any full measure the initiative of his workmen
    unless he felt that he was giving them something more than
    they usually receive from their employers. Only those
    among the readers of this paper who have been managers
    or who have worked themselves at a trade realize how far
    the average workman falls short of giving his employer his
    full initiative. It is well within the mark to state that in
    nineteen out of twenty industrial establishments the
    workmen believe it to be directly against their interests to
    give their employers their best initiative, and that instead of
    working hard to do the largest possible amount of work and
    the best quality of work for their employers, they
    deliberately work as slowly as they dare while they at the
    same time try to make those over them believe that they
    are working fast.

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (2 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    The writer repeats, therefore, that in order to have any
    hope of obtaining the initiative of his workmen the manager
    must give some special incentive to his men beyond that
    which is given to the average of the trade. This incentive
    can be given in several different ways, as, for example, the
    hope of rapid promotion or advancement; higher wages,
    either in the form of generous piece-work prices or of a
    premium or bonus of some kind for good and rapid work;
    shorter hours of labor; better surroundings and working
    conditions than are ordinarily given, etc., and, above all,
    this special incentive should be accompanied by that
    personal consideration for, and friendly contact with, his
    workmen which comes only from a genuine and kindly
    interest in the welfare of those under him. It is only by
    giving a special inducement or “incentive” of this kind that
    the employer can hope even approximately to get the
    “initiative” of his workmen. Under the ordinary type of
    management the necessity for offering the workman a
    special inducement has come to be so generally recognized
    that a large proportion of those most interested in the
    subject look upon the adoption of some one of the modern
    schemes for paying men (such as piece work, the premium
    plan, or the bonus plan, for instance) as practically the
    whole system of management. Under scientific
    management, however, the particular pay system which is
    adopted is merely one of the subordinate elements.

    Broadly speaking, then, the best type of management in
    ordinary use may be defined as management in which the
    workmen give their best initiative and in return receive
    some special incentive from their employers. This type of
    management will be referred to as the management of
    “initiative and incentive” in contradistinction to scientific
    management, or task management, with which it is to be
    compared.

    The writer hopes that the management of “initiative and
    incentive” will be recognized as representing the best type
    in ordinary use, and in fact he believes that it will be hard to
    persuade the average manager that anything better exists
    in the whole field than this type. The task which the writer
    has before him, then, is the difficult one of trying to prove
    in a thoroughly convincing way that there is another type of
    management which is not only better but overwhelmingly
    better than the management of “initiative and incentive.”

    The universal prejudice in favor of the management of
    “initiative and incentive” is so strong that no mere
    theoretical advantages which can be pointed out will be
    likely to convince the average manager that any other
    system is better. It will be upon a series of practical
    illustrations of the actual working of the two systems that
    the writer will depend in his efforts to prove that scientific
    management is so greatly superior to other types. Certain
    elementary principles, a certain philosophy, will however be
    recognized as the essence of that which is being illustrated

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (3 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    in all of the practical examples which will be given. And the
    broad principles in which the scientific system differs from
    the ordinary or “rule-of-thumb” system are so simple in
    their nature that it seems desirable to describe them before
    starting with the illustrations.

    Under the old type of management success depends almost
    entirely upon getting the “initiative” of the workmen, and it
    is indeed a rare case in which this initiative is really
    attained. Under scientific management the “initiative” of the
    workmen (that is, their hard work, their good-will, and their
    ingenuity) is obtained with absolute uniformity and to a
    greater extent than is possible under the old system; and in
    addition to this improvement on the part of the men, the
    managers assume new burdens, new duties, and
    responsibilities never dreamed of in the past. The managers
    assume, for instance, the burden of gathering together all of
    the traditional knowledge which in the past has been
    possessed by the workmen and then of classifying,
    tabulating, and reducing this knowledge to rules, laws, and
    formulae which are immensely helpful to the workmen in
    doing their daily work. In addition to developing a science in
    this way, the management take on three other types of
    duties which involve new and heavy burdens for themselves.

    These new duties are grouped under four heads:

    First. They develop a science for each element of a man’s
    work, which replaces the old rule-of.-thumb method.

    Second. They scientifically select and then train, teach, and
    develop the workman, whereas in the past he chose his own
    work and trained himself as best he could.

    Third. They heartily cooperate with the men so as to insure
    all of the work being done in accordance with the principles
    of the science which has been developed.

    Fourth. There is an almost equal division of the work and
    the responsibility between the management and the
    workmen. The management take over all work for which
    they are better fitted than the workmen, while in the past
    almost all of the work and the greater part of the
    responsibility were thrown upon the men.

    It is this combination of the initiative of the workmen,
    coupled with the new types of work done by the
    management, that makes scientific management so much
    more efficient than the old plan.

    Three of these elements exist in many cases, under the
    management of “initiative and incentive,” in a small and
    rudimentary way, but they are, under this management, of
    minor importance, whereas under scientific management
    they form the very essence of the whole system.

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (4 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    The fourth of these elements, “an almost equal division of
    the responsibility between the management and the
    workmen,” requires further explanation. The philosophy of
    the management of initiative and incentive makes it
    necessary for each workman to bear almost the entire
    responsibility for the general plan as well as for each detail
    of his work, and in many cases for his implements as well.
    In addition to this he must do all of the actual physical
    labor. The development of a science, on the other hand,
    involves the establishment of many rules, laws, and
    formulae which replace the judgment of the individual
    workman and which can be effectively used only after
    having been systematically recorded, indexed, etc. The
    practical use of scientific data also calls for a room in which
    to keep the books, records, etc., and a desk for the planner
    to work at.

    Thus all of the planning which under the old system was
    done by the workman, as a result of his personal
    experience, must of necessity under the new system be
    done by the management in accordance with the laws of the
    science; because even if the workman was well suited to
    the development and use of scientific data, it would be
    physically impossible for him to work at his machine and at
    a desk at the same time. It is also clear that in most cases
    one type of man is needed to plan ahead and an entirely
    different type to execute the work.

    The man in the planning room, whose specialty under
    scientific management is planning ahead, invariably finds
    that the work can be done better and more economically by
    a subdivision of the labor; each act of each mechanic, for
    example, should. be preceded by various preparatory acts
    done by other men. And all of this involves, as we have
    said, “an almost equal division of the responsibility and the
    work between the management and the workman.”

    To summarize: Under the management of “initiative and
    incentive” practically the whole problem is “up to the
    workman,” while under scientific management fully one-half
    of the problem is “up to the management.”

    Perhaps the most prominent single element in modern
    scientific management is the task idea. The work of every
    workman is fully planned out by the management at least
    one day in advance, and each man receives in most cases
    complete written instructions, describing in detail the task
    which he is to accomplish, as well as the means to be used
    in doing the work. And the work planned in advance in this
    way constitutes a task which is to be solved, as explained
    above, not by the workman alone, but in almost all cases by
    the joint effort of the workman and the management. This
    task specifies not only what is to be done but how it is to be
    done and the exact time allowed for doing it. And whenever
    the workman succeeds in doing his task right, and within

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (5 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    the time limit specified, he receives an addition of from 30
    per cent to 100 per cent to his ordinary wages. These tasks
    are carefully planned, so that both good and careful work
    are called for in their performance, but it should be
    distinctly understood that in no case is the workman called
    upon to work at a pace which would be injurious to his
    health. The task is always so regulated that the man who is
    well suited to his job will thrive while working at this rate
    during a long term of years and grow happier and more
    prosperous, instead of being overworked. Scientific
    management consists very largely in preparing for and
    carrying out these tasks.

    The writer is fully aware that to perhaps most of the readers
    of this paper the four elements which differentiate the new
    management from the old will at first appear to be merely
    high-sounding phrases; and he would again repeat that he
    has no idea of convincing the reader of their value merely
    through announcing their existence. His hope of carrying
    conviction rests upon demonstrating the tremendous force
    and effect of these four elements through a series of
    practical illustrations. It will be shown, first, that they can
    be applied absolutely to all classes of work, from the most
    elementary to the most intricate; and second, that when
    they are applied, the results must of necessity be
    overwhelmingly greater than those which it is possible to
    attain under the management of initiative and incentive.

    The first illustration is that of handling pig iron, and this
    work is chosen because it is typical of perhaps the crudest
    and most elementary form of labor which is performed by
    man. This work is done by men with no other implements
    than their hands. The pig-iron handler stoops down, picks
    up a pig weighing about 92 pounds, walks for a few feet or
    yards and then drops it on to the ground or upon a pile.
    This work is so crude and elementary in its nature that the
    writer firmly believes that it would be possible to train an
    intelligent, gorilla so as to become a more efficient pig-iron
    handler than any man can be. Yet it will be shown that the
    science of handling pig iron is so great and amounts to so
    much that it is impossible for the man who is best suited to
    this type of work to understand the principles of this
    science, or even to work in accordance with these principles
    without the aid of a man better educated than he is. And
    the further illustrations to be given will make it clear that in
    almost all of the mechanic arts the science which underlies
    each workman’s act is so great and amounts to so much
    that the workman who is best suited actually to do the work
    is incapable (either through lack of education or through
    insufficient mental capacity) of understanding this science.
    This is announced as a general principle, the truth of which
    will become apparent as one illustration after another is
    given. After showing these four elements in the handling of
    pig iron, several illustrations will be given of their
    application to different kinds of work in the field of the
    mechanic arts, at intervals in a rising scale, beginning with

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (6 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    the simplest and ending with the more intricate forms of
    labor.

    One of the first pieces of work undertaken by us, when the
    writer started to introduce scientific management into the
    Bethlehem Steel Company, was to handle pig iron on task
    work. The opening of the Spanish War found some 80,000
    tons of pig iron placed in small piles in an open field
    adjoining the works. Prices for pig iron had been so low that
    it could not be sold at a profit, and it therefore had been
    stored. With the opening of the Spanish War the price of pig
    iron rose, and this large accumulation of iron was sold. This
    gave us a good opportunity to show the workmen, as well
    as the owners and managers of the works, on a fairly large
    scale the advantages of task work over the old-fashioned
    day work and piece work, in doing a very elementary class
    of work.

    The Bethlehem Steel Company had five blast furnaces, the
    product of which had been handled by a pig-iron gang for
    many years. This gang, at this time, consisted of about 75
    men. They were good, average pig-iron handlers, were
    under an excellent foreman who himself had been a pig-iron
    handler, and the work was done, on the whole, about as
    fast and as cheaply as it was anywhere else at that time.

    A railroad switch was run out into the field, right along the
    edge of the piles of pig iron. An inclined plank was placed
    against the side of a car, and each man picked up from his
    pile a pig of iron weighing about 92 pounds, walked up the
    inclined plank and dropped it on the end of the car.

    We found that this gang were loading on the average about
    12 and a half long tons per man per day. We were surprised
    to find, after studying the matter, that a first-class pig-iron
    handler ought to handle between 47, and 48 long tons per
    day, instead of 12 and a half tons. This task seemed to us
    so very large that we were obliged to go over our work
    several times before we were absolutely sure that we were
    right. Once we were sure, however, that 47 tons was a
    proper day’s work for a first-class pig-iron handler, the task
    which faced us as managers under the modern scientific
    plan was clearly before us. It was our duty to see that the
    80,000 tons of pig iron was loaded on to the cars at the rate
    of 47 tons per man per day, in place of 12 and a half tons,
    at which rate the work was then being done. And it was
    further our duty to see that this work was done without
    bringing on a strike among the men, without any quarrel
    with the men, and to see that the men were happier and
    better contented when loading at the new rate of 47 tons
    than they were when loading at the old rate of 12 and a half
    tons.

    Our first step was the scientific selection of the workman. In
    dealing with workmen under this type of management, it is
    an inflexible rule to talk to and deal with only one man at a

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (7 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    time, since each workman has his own special abilities and
    limitations, and since we are not dealing with men in
    masses, but are trying to develop each individual man to his
    highest state of efficiency and prosperity. Our first step was
    to find the proper workman to begin with. We therefore
    carefully watched and studied these 75 men for three or
    four days, at the end of which time we had picked out four
    men who appeared to be physically able to handle pig iron
    at the rate of 47 tons per day. A careful study was then
    made of each of these men. We looked up their history as
    far back as practicable and thorough inquiries were made as
    to the character, habits, and the ambition of each of them.
    Finally we selected one from among the four as the most
    likely man to start with. He was a little Pennsylvania
    Dutchman who had been observed to trot back home for a
    mile or so after his work in the evening about as fresh as he
    was when he came trotting down to work in the morning.
    We found that upon wages of $1.15 a day he had succeeded
    in buying a small plot of ground, and that he was engaged
    in putting up the walls of a little house for himself in the
    morning before starting to work and at night after leaving.
    He also had the reputation of being exceedingly “close,”
    that is, of placing a very high value on a dollar. As one man
    whom we talked to about him said, “A penny looks about
    the size of a cart-wheel to him.” This man we will call
    Schmidt.

    The task before us, then, narrowed itself down to getting
    Schmidt to handle 47 tons of pig iron per day and making
    him glad to do it. This was done as follows. Schmidt was
    called out from among the gang of pig-iron handlers and
    talked to somewhat in this way:

    “Schmidt, are you a high-priced man?”

    “Vell, I don’t know vat you mean.”

    “Oh yes, you do. What I want to know is whether you are a
    high-priced man or not.”

    “Vell, I don’t know vat you mean.”

    “Oh, come now, you answer my questions. What I want to
    find out is whether you are a high-priced man or one of
    these cheap fellows here. What I want to find out is whether
    you want to earn $1.85 a day or whether you are satisfied
    with $1.15, just the same as all those cheap fellows are
    getting.”

    “Did I vant $1.85 a day? Vas dot a high-priced man? Vell,
    yes, I vas a high-priced man.”

    “Oh, you’re aggravating me. Of course you want $1.85 a
    day–every one wants it! You know perfectly well that that
    has very little to do with your being a high-priced man. For

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (8 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    goodness’ sake answer my questions, and don’t waste any
    more of my time. Now come over here. You see that pile of
    pig iron?”

    “Yes.”

    “You see that car?”

    “Yes.”

    “Well, if you are a high-priced man, you will load that pig
    iron on that car tomorrow for $1.85. Now do wake up and
    answer my question. Tell me whether you are a high-priced
    man or not.”

    “Vell, did I got $1.85 for loading dot pig iron on dot car to-
    morrow?”

    “Yes, of course you do, and you get $1.85 for loading a pile
    like that every day right through the year. That is what a
    high-priced man does, and you know it just as well as I do.”

    “Vell, dot’s all right. I could load dot pig iron on the car to-
    morrow for $1.85, and I get it every day, don’t I?”

    “Certainly you do–certainly you do.”

    “Vell, den, I vas a high-priced man.”

    “Now, hold on, hold on. You know just as well as I do that a
    high-priced man has to do exactly as he’s told from morning
    till night. You have seen this man here before, haven’t you?”

    “No, I never saw him.”

    “Well, if you are a high-priced man, you will do exactly as
    this man tells you tomorrow, from morning till night. When
    he tells you to pick up a pig and walk, you pick it up and
    you walk, and when he tells you to sit down and rest, you
    sit down. You do that right straight through the day. And
    what’s more, no back talk. Now a high-priced man does just
    what he’s told to do, and no back talk. Do you understand
    that? When this man tells you to walk, you walk; when he
    tells you to sit down, you sit down, and you don’t talk back
    at him. Now you come on to work here to-morrow morning
    and I’ll know before night whether you are really a high-
    priced man or not.”

    This seems to be rather rough talk. And indeed it would be
    if applied to an educated mechanic, or even an intelligent
    laborer. With a man of the mentally sluggish type of
    Schmidt it is appropriate and not unkind, since it is effective
    in fixing his attention on the high wages which he wants and
    away from what, if it were called to his attention, he

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (9 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    probably would consider impossibly hard work.

    What would Schmidt’s answer be if he were talked to in a
    manner which is usual under the management of “initiative
    and incentive”? say, as follows:

    “Now, Schmidt, you are a first-class pig-iron handler and
    know your business well. You have been handling at the
    rate of 12 and a half tons per day. I have given
    considerable study to handling pig iron, and feel sure that
    you could do a much larger day’s work than you have been
    doing. Now don’t you think that if you really tried you could
    handle 47 tons of pig iron per day, instead of 12 and a half
    tons?”

    What do you think Schmidt’s answer would be to this?

    Schmidt started to work, and all day long, and at regular
    intervals, was told by the man who stood over him with a
    watch, “Now pick up a pig and walk. Now sit down and rest.
    Now walk–now rest,” etc. He worked when he was told to
    work, and rested when he was told to rest, and at half-past
    five in the afternoon had his 47 and a half tons loaded on
    the car. And he practically never failed to work at this pace
    and do the task that was set him during the three years
    that the writer was at Bethlehem. And throughout this time
    he averaged a little more than $1.85 per day, whereas
    before he had never received over $1.15 per day, which
    was the ruling rate of wages at that time in Bethlehem. That
    is, he received 60 per cent. higher wages than were paid to
    other men who were not working on task work. One man
    after another was picked out and trained to handle pig iron
    at the rate of 47 and a half tons per day until all of the pig
    iron was handled at this rate, and the men were receiving
    60 per cent. more wages than other workmen around them.

    The writer has given above a brief description of three of
    the four elements which constitute the essence of scientific
    management: first, the careful selection of the workman,
    and, second and third, the method of first inducing and then
    training and helping the workman to work according to the
    scientific method. Nothing has as yet been said about the
    science of handling pig iron. The writer trusts, however, that
    before leaving this illustration the reader will be thoroughly
    convinced that there is a science of handling pig iron, and
    further that this science amounts to so much that the man
    who is suited to handle pig iron cannot possibly understand
    it, nor even work in accordance with the laws of this
    science, without the help of those who are over him.

    The writer came into the machine-shop of the Midvale Steel
    Company in 1878, after having served an apprenticeship as
    a pattern-maker and as a machinist. This was close to the
    end of the long period of depression following the panic of
    1873, and business was so poor that it was impossible for
    many mechanics to get work at their trades. For this reason

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (10 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    he was obliged to start as a day laborer instead of working
    as a mechanic. Fortunately for him, soon after he came into
    the shop the clerk of the shop was found stealing. There
    was no one else available, and so, having more education
    than the other laborers (since he had been prepared for
    college) he was given the position of clerk. Shortly after this
    he was given work as a machinist in running one of the
    lathes, and, as he turned out rather more work than other
    machinists were doing on similar lathes, after several
    months was made gang boss over the lathes.

    Almost all of the work of this shop had been done on piece
    work for several years. As was usual then, and in fact as is
    still usual in most of the shops in this country, the shop was
    really run by the workmen, and not by the bosses. The
    workmen together had carefully planned just how fast each
    job should be done, and they had set a pace for each
    machine throughout the shop, which was limited to about
    one-third of a good day’s work. Every new workman who
    came into the shop was told at once by the other men
    exactly how much of each kind of work he was to do, and
    unless he obeyed these instructions he was sure before long
    to be driven out of the place by the men.

    As soon as the writer was made gang-boss, one after
    another of the men came to him and talked somewhat as
    follows:

    “Now, Fred we’re very glad to see that you’ve been made
    gang-boss. You know the game all right, and we’re sure
    that you’re not likely to be a piece-work hog. You come
    along with us, and every-thing will be all right, but if you try
    breaking any of these rates you can be mighty sure that
    we’ll throw you over the fence.”

    The writer told them plainly that he was now working on the
    side of the management, and that he proposed to do
    whatever he could to get a fair day’s work out of the lathes.
    This immediately started a war; in most cases a friendly
    war, because the men who were under him were his
    personal friends, but none the less a war, which as time
    went on grew more and more bitter. The writer used every
    expedient to make them do a fair day’s work, such as
    discharging or lowering the wages of the more stubborn
    men who refused to make any improvement, and such as
    lowering the piece-work price, hiring green men, and
    personally teaching them bow to do the work, with the
    promise from them that when they had learned how, they
    would then do a fair day’s work. While the men constantly
    brought such pressure to bear (both inside and outside the
    works) upon all those who started to increase their output
    that they were finally compelled to do about as the rest did,
    or else quit. No one who has not had this experience can
    have an idea of the bitterness which is gradually developed
    in such a struggle. In a war of this kind the workmen have
    one expedient which is usually effective. They use their

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (11 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    ingenuity to contrive various ways in which the machines
    which they are running are broken or damaged–apparently
    by accident, or in the regular course of work–and this they
    always lay at the door of the foreman, who has forced them
    to drive the machine so hard that it is overstrained and is
    being ruined. And there are few foremen indeed who are
    able to stand up against the combined pressure of all of the
    men in the shop. In this case the problem was complicated
    by the fact that the shop ran both day and night.

    The writer had two advantages, however, which are not
    possessed by the ordinary foreman, and these came,
    curiously enough, from the fact that he was not the son of a
    working man.

    First, owing to the fact that he happened not to be of
    working parents, the owners of the company believed that
    he had the interest of the works more at heart than the
    other workmen, and they therefore had more confidence in
    his word than they did in that of the machinists who were
    under him. So that, when the machinists reported to the
    Superintendent that the machines were being smashed up
    because an incompetent foreman was overstraining them,
    the Superintendent accepted the word of the writer when he
    said that these men were deliberately breaking their
    machines as a part of the piece-work war which was going
    on, and he also allowed the writer to make the only
    effective answer to this Vandalism on the part of the men,
    namely: “There will be no more accidents to the machines
    in this shop. If any part of a machine is broken the man in
    charge of it must pay at least a part of the cost of its repair,
    and the fines collected in this way will all be handed over to
    the mutual beneficial association to help care for sick
    workmen.” This soon stopped the willful breaking of
    machines.

    Second. If the writer had been one of the workmen, and
    had lived where they lived, they would have brought such
    social pressure to bear upon him that it would have been
    impossible to have stood out against them. He would have
    been called “scab” and other foul names every time he
    appeared on the street, his wife would have been abused,
    and his children would have been stoned. Once or twice he
    was begged by some of his friends among the workmen not
    to walk home, about two and a half miles along the lonely
    path by the side of the railway. He was told that if he
    continued to do this it would be at the risk of his life. In all
    such cases, however, a display of timidity is apt to increase
    rather than diminish the risk, so the writer told these men
    to say to the other men in the shop that he proposed to
    walk home every night right up that railway track; that he
    never had carried and never would carry any weapon of any
    kind, and that they could shoot and be d——.

    After about three years of this kind of struggling, the output
    of the machines had been materially increased, in many

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (12 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    cases doubled, and as a result the writer had been
    promoted from one gang-boss-ship to another until he
    became foreman of the shop. For any right-minded man,
    however, this success is in no sense a recompense for the
    bitter relations which he is forced to maintain with all of
    those around him. Life which is one continuous struggle
    with other men is hardly worth living. His workman friends
    came to him continually and asked him, in a personal,
    friendly way, whether he would advise them, for their own
    best interest, to turn out more work. And, as a truthful
    man, he had to tell them that if he were in their place he
    would fight against turning out any more work, just as they
    were doing, because under the piece-work system they
    would be allowed to earn no more wages than they had
    been earning, and yet they would be made to work harder.

    Soon after being made foreman, therefore, he decided to
    make a determined effort to in some way change the
    system of management, so that the interests of the
    workmen and the management should become the same,
    instead of antagonistic. This resulted, some three years
    later, in the starting of the type of management which is
    described in papers presented to the American Society of
    Mechanical Engineers entitled “A Piece-Rate System” and
    “Shop Management.”

    In preparation for this system the writer realized that the
    greatest obstacle to harmonious cooperation between the
    workmen and the management lay in the ignorance of the
    management as to what really constitutes a proper day’s
    work for a workman. He fully realized that although he was
    foreman of the shop, the combined knowledge and skill of
    the workmen who were under him was certainly ten times
    as great as his own. He therefore obtained the permission
    of Mr. William Sellers, who was at that time the President of
    the Midvale Steel Company, to spend some money in a
    careful, scientific study of the time required to do various
    kinds of work.

    Mr. Sellers allowed this more as a reward for having, to a
    certain extent, “made good” as foreman of the shop in
    getting more work out of the men, than for any other
    reason. He stated, however, that he did not believe that any
    scientific study of this sort would give results of much value.

    Among several investigations which were undertaken at this
    time, one was an attempt to find some rule, or law, which
    would enable a foreman to know in advance how much of
    any kind of heavy laboring work a man who was well suited
    to his job ought to do in a day; that is, to study the tiring
    effect of heavy labor upon a first-class man. Our first step
    was to employ a young college graduate to look up all that
    had been written on the subject in English, German, and
    French. Two classes of experiments had been made: one by
    physiologists who were studying the endurance of the
    human animal, and the other by engineers who wished to

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (13 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    determine what fraction of a horse-power a man-power
    was. These experiments had been made largely upon men
    who were lifting loads by means of turning the crank of a
    winch from which weights were suspended, and others who
    were engaged in walking, running, and lifting weights in
    various ways. However, the records of these investigations
    were so meager that no law of any value could be deduced
    from them. We therefore started a series of experiments of
    our own.

    Two first-class laborers were selected, men who had proved
    themselves to be physically powerful and who were also
    good steady workers. These men were paid double wages
    during the experiments, and were told that they must work
    to the best of their ability at all times, and that we should
    make certain tests with them from time to time to find
    whether they were “soldiering” or not, and that the moment
    either one of them started to try to deceive us he would be
    discharged. They worked to the best of their ability
    throughout the time that they were being observed.

    Now it must be clearly understood that in these experiments
    we were not trying to find the maximum work that a man
    could do on a short spurt or for a few days, but that our
    endeavor was to learn what really constituted a full day’s
    work for a first-class man; the best day’s work that a man
    could properly do, year in and year out, and still thrive
    under. These men were given all kinds of tasks, which were
    carried out each day under the close observation of the
    young college man who was conducting the experiments,
    and who at the same time noted with a stop-watch the
    proper time for all of the motions that were made by the
    men. Every element in any way connected with the work
    which we believed could have a bearing on the result was
    carefully studied and recorded. What we hoped ultimately to
    determine was what fraction of a horse-power a man was
    able to exert, that is, how many foot-pounds of work a man
    could do in a day.

    After completing this series of experiments, therefore, each
    man’s work for each day was translated into foot-pounds of
    energy, and to our surprise we found that there was no
    constant or uniform relation between the foot-pounds of
    energy which the man exerted during a day and the tiring
    effect of his work. On some kinds of work the man would be
    tired out when doing perhaps not more than one-eighth of a
    horse-power, while in others he would be tired to no greater
    extent by doing half a horse-power of work.

    We failed, therefore, to find any law which was an accurate
    guide to the maximum day’s work for a first-class workman.

    A large amount of very valuable data had been obtained,
    which enabled us to know, for many kinds of labor, what
    was a proper day’s work. It did not seem wise, however, at
    this time to spend any more money in trying to find the

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (14 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    exact law which we were after. Some years later, when
    more money was available for this purpose, a second series
    of experiments was made, similar to the first, but some
    what more thorough.

    This, however, resulted as the first experiments, in
    obtaining valuable information but not in the development
    of a law. Again, some years later, a third series of
    experiments was made, and this time no trouble was spared
    in our endeavor to make the work thorough. Every minute
    element which could in anyway affect the problem was
    carefully noted and studied, and two college men devoted
    about three months to the experiments. After this data was
    again translated into foot-pounds of energy exerted for each
    man each day, it became perfectly clear that there is no
    direct relation between the horse-power which a man exerts
    (that is, his foot-pounds of energy per day) and the tiring
    effect of the work on the man. The writer, however, was
    quite as firmly convinced as ever that some definite, clear-
    cut law existed as to what constitutes a full day’s work for a
    first-class laborer, and our data had been so carefully
    collected and recorded that he felt sure that the necessary
    information was included somewhere in the records. The
    problem of developing this law from the accumulated facts
    was therefore handed over to Mr. Carl G. Barth, who is a
    better mathematician than any of the rest of us, and we
    decided to investigate the problem in a new way, by
    graphically representing each element of the work through
    plotting curves, which should give us, as it were, a bird’s-
    eye view of every element. In a comparatively short time
    Mr. Barth had discovered the law governing the tiring effect
    of heavy labor on a first-class man. And it is so simple in its
    nature that it is truly remarkable that it should not have
    been discovered and clearly understood years before. The
    law which was developed is as follows:

    The law is confined to that class of work in which the limit of
    a man’s capacity is reached because he is tired out. It is the
    law of heavy laboring, corresponding to the work of the cart
    horse, rather than that of the trotter. Practically all such
    work consists of a heavy pull or a push on the man’s arms,
    that is, the man’s strength is exerted by either lifting or
    pushing something which he grasps in his hands. And the
    law is that for each given pull or push on the man’s arms it
    is possible for the workman to be under load for only a
    definite percentage of the day. For example, when pig iron
    is being handled (each pig weighing 92 pounds), a first-
    class workman can only be under load 43 per cent of the
    day. He must be entirely free from load during 57 per cent
    of the day. And as the load becomes lighter, the percentage
    of the day under which the man can remain under load
    increases. So that, if the workman is handling a half-pig,
    weighing 46 pounds, he can then be under load 58 per cent
    of the day, and only has to rest during 42 per cent. As the
    weight grows lighter the man can remain under load during
    a larger and larger percentage of the day, until finally a load

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (15 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    is reached which he can carry in his hands all day long
    without being tired out. When that point has been arrived at
    this law ceases to be useful as a guide to a laborer’s
    endurance, and some other law must be found which
    indicates the man’s capacity for work.

    When a laborer is carrying a piece of pig iron weighing 92
    pounds in his hands, it tires him about as much to stand still
    under the load as it does to walk with it, since his arm
    muscles are under the same severe tension whether he is
    moving or not. A man, however, who stands still under a
    load is exerting no horse-power whatever, and this accounts
    for the fact that no constant relation could be traced in
    various kinds of heavy laboring work between the foot-
    pounds of energy exerted and the tiring effect of the work
    on the man. It will also be clear that in all work of this kind
    it is necessary for the arms of the workman to be
    completely free from load (that is, for the workman to rest)
    at frequent intervals. Throughout the time that the man is
    under a heavy load the tissues of his arm muscles are in
    process of degeneration, and frequent periods of rest are
    required in order that the blood may have a chance to
    restore these tissues to their normal condition.

    To return now to our pig-iron handlers at the Bethlehem
    Steel Company. If Schmidt had been allowed to attack the
    pile of 47 tons of pig iron without the guidance or direction
    of a man who understood the art, or science, of handling
    pig iron, in his desire to earn his high wages he would
    probably have tired himself out by 11 or 12 o’clock in the
    day. He would have kept so steadily at work that his
    muscles would not have had the proper periods of rest
    absolutely needed for recuperation, and he would have been
    completely exhausted early in the day. By having a man,
    however, who understood this law, stand over him and
    direct his work, day after day, until he acquired the habit of
    resting at proper intervals, he was able to work at an even
    gait all day long without unduly tiring himself.

    Now one of the very first requirements for a man who is fit
    to handle pig iron as a regular occupation that he shall be
    so stupid and so phlegmatic that he more nearly resembles
    in his mental make-up the ox than any other type. The man
    who is mentally alert and intelligent is for this very reason
    entirely unsuited to what would, for him, be the grinding
    monotony of work of this character. Therefore the workman
    who is best suited to handling pig iron is unable to
    understand the real science of doing this class of work. He
    is so stupid that the word “percentage” has no meaning to
    him, and he must consequently be trained by a man more
    intelligent than himself into the habit of working in
    accordance with the laws of this science before he can be
    successful.

    The writer trusts that it is now clear that even in the case of
    the most elementary form of labor that is known, there is a

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (16 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    science, and that when the man best suited to this class of
    work has been carefully selected, when the science of doing
    the work has been developed, and when the carefully
    selected man has been trained to work in accordance with
    this science, the results obtained must of necessity be
    overwhelmingly greater than those which are possible under
    the plan of “initiative and incentive.”

    Let us, however, again turn to the case of these pig-iron
    handlers, and see whether, under the ordinary type of
    management, it would not have been possible to obtain
    practically the same results.

    The writer has put the problem before many good
    managers, and asked them whether, under premium work,
    piece work, or any of the ordinary plans of management,
    they would be likely even to approximate 47 tons per man
    per day, and not a man has suggested that an output of
    over 18 to 25 tons could be attained by any of the ordinary
    expedients. It will be remembered that the Bethlehem men
    were loading only 12 1/2 tons per man.

    To go into the matter in more detail, however: As to the
    scientific selection of the men, it is a fact that in this gang
    of 75 pig-iron handlers only about one man in eight was
    physically capable of handling 47 1/2 tons per day. With the
    very best of intentions, the other seven out of eight men
    were physically unable to work at this pace. Now the one
    man in eight who was able to do this work was in no sense
    superior to the other men who were working on the gang.
    He merely happened to be a man of the type of the ox,–no
    rare specimen of humanity, difficult to find and therefore
    very highly prized. On the contrary, he was a man so stupid
    that he was unfitted to do most kinds of laboring work,
    even. The selection of the man, then, does not involve
    finding some extraordinary individual, but merely picking
    out from among very ordinary men the few who are
    especially suited to this type of work. Although in this
    particular gang only one man in eight was suited to doing
    the work, we had not the slightest difficulty in getting all the
    men who were needed–some of them from inside of the
    works and others from the neighboring country–who were
    exactly suited to the job.

    Under the management of “initiative and incentive” the
    attitude of the management is that of “putting the work up
    to the workmen.” What likelihood would there be, then,
    under the old type of management, of these men properly
    selecting themselves for pig-iron handling? Would they be
    likely to get rid of seven men out of eight from their own
    gang and retain only the eighth man? No! And no expedient
    could be devised which would make these men properly
    select themselves. Even if they fully realized the necessity
    of doing so in order to obtain high wages (and they are not
    sufficiently intelligent properly to grasp this necessity), the
    fact that their friends or their brothers who were working

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (17 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    right alongside of them would temporarily be thrown out of
    a job because they were not suited to this kind of work
    would entirely prevent them from properly selecting
    themselves, that is, from removing the seven out of eight
    men on the gang who were unsuited to pig-iron handling.

    As to the possibility, under the old type of management, of
    inducing these pig-iron handlers (after they had been
    properly selected) to work in accordance with the science of
    doing heavy laboring, namely, having proper scientifically
    determined periods of rest in close sequence to periods of
    work. As has been indicated before, the essential idea of the
    ordinary types of management is that each workman has
    become more skilled in his own trade than it is possible for
    any one in the management to be, and that, therefore, the
    details of how the work shall best be done must be left to
    him. The idea, then, of taking one man after another and
    training him under a competent teacher into new working
    habits until he continually and habitually works in
    accordance with scientific laws, which have been developed
    by some one else, is directly antagonistic to the old idea
    that each workman can best regulate his own way of doing
    the work. And besides this, the man suited to handling pig
    iron is too stupid properly to train himself. Thus it will be
    seen that with the ordinary types of management the
    development of scientific knowledge to replace rule of
    thumb, the scientific selection of the men, and inducing the
    men to work in accordance with these scientific principles
    are entirely out of the question. And this because the
    philosophy of the old management puts the entire
    responsibility upon the workmen, while the philosophy of
    the new places a great part of it upon the management.

    With most readers great sympathy will be aroused because
    seven out of eight of these pig-iron handlers were thrown
    out of a job. This sympathy is entirely wasted, because
    almost all of them were immediately given other jobs with
    the Bethlehem Steel Company. And indeed it should be
    understood that the removal of these men from pig-iron
    handling, for which they were unfit, was really a kindness to
    themselves, because it was the first step toward finding
    them work for which they were peculiarly fitted, and at
    which, after receiving proper training, they could
    permanently and legitimately earn higher wages.

    Although the reader may be convinced that there is a
    certain science back of the handling of pig iron, still it is
    more than likely that he is still skeptical as to the existence
    of a science for doing other kinds of laboring. One of the
    important objects of this paper is to convince its readers
    that every single act of every workman can be reduced to a
    science. With the hope of fully convincing the reader of this
    fact, therefore, the writer proposes to give several more
    simple illustrations from among the thousands which are at
    hand.

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (18 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    For example, the average man would question whether
    there is much of any science in the work of shoveling. Yet
    there is but little doubt, if any intelligent reader of this
    paper were deliberately to set out to find what may be
    called the foundation of the science of shoveling, that with
    perhaps 15 to 20 hours of thought and analysis he would be
    almost sure to have arrived at the essence of this science.
    On the other hand, so completely are the rule-of-thumb
    ideas still dominant that the writer has never met a single
    shovel contractor to whom it had ever even occurred that
    there was such a thing as the science of shoveling. This
    science is so elementary as to be almost self-evident.

    For a first-class shoveler there is a given shovel load at
    which he will do his biggest day’s work. What is this shovel
    load? Will a first-class man do more work per day with a
    shovel load of 5 pounds, 10 pounds, 15 pounds, 20, 25, 30,
    or 40 pounds? Now this is a question which can be
    answered only through carefully made experiments. By first
    selecting two or three first-class shovelers, and paying them
    extra wages for doing trustworthy work, and then gradually
    varying the shovel load and having all the conditions
    accompanying the work carefully observed for several
    weeks by men who were used to experimenting, it was
    found that a first-class man would do his biggest day’s work
    with a shovel load of about 21 pounds. For instance, that
    this man would shovel a larger tonnage per day with a 21-
    pound load than with a 24-pound load or than with an 18-
    pound load on his shovel. It is, of course, evident that no
    shoveler can always take a load of exactly 21 pounds on his
    shovel, but nevertheless, although his load may vary 3 or 4
    pounds one way or the other, either below or above the 21
    pounds, he will do his biggest day’s work when his average
    for the day is about 21 pounds.

    The writer does not wish it to be understood that this is the
    whole of the art or science of shoveling. There are many
    other elements, which together go to make up this science.
    But he wishes to indicate the important effect which this
    one piece of scientific knowledge has upon the work of
    shoveling.

    At the works of the Bethlehem Steel Company, for example,
    as a result of this law, instead of allowing each shoveler to
    select and own his own shovel, it became necessary to
    provide some 8 to 10 different kinds of shovels, etc., each
    one appropriate to handling a given type of material not
    only so as to enable the men to handle an average load of
    21 pounds, but also to adapt the shovel to several other
    requirements which become perfectly evident when this
    work is studied as a science. A large shovel tool room was
    built, in which were stored not only shovels but carefully
    designed and standardized labor implements of all kinds,
    such as picks, crowbars, etc. This made it possible to issue
    to each workman a shovel which would hold a load of 21
    pounds of whatever class of material they were to handle: a

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (19 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    small shovel for ore, say, or a large one for ashes. Iron ore
    is one of the heavy materials which are handled in a works
    of this kind, and rice coal, owing to the fact that it is so
    slippery on the shovel, is one of the lightest materials. And
    it was found on studying the rule-of-thumb plan at the
    Bethlehem Steel Company, where each shoveler owned his
    own shovel, that he would frequently go from shoveling ore,
    with a load of about 30 pounds per shovel, to handling rice
    coal, with a load on the same shovel of less than 4 pounds.
    In the one case, he was so overloaded that it was
    impossible for him to do a full day’s work, and in the other
    case he was so ridiculously underloaded that it was
    manifestly impossible to even approximate a day’s work.

    Briefly to illustrate some of the other elements which go to
    make tip the science of shoveling, thousands of stop-watch
    observations were made to study just how quickly a laborer,
    provided in each case with the proper type of shovel, can
    push his shovel into the pile of materials and then draw it
    out properly loaded. These observations were made first
    when pushing the shovel into the body of the pile. Next
    when shoveling on a dirt bottom, that is, at the outside
    edge of the pile, and next with a wooden bottom, and finally
    with an iron bottom. Again a similar accurate time study
    was made of the time required to swing the shovel
    backward and then throw the load for a given horizontal
    distance, accompanied by a given height. This time study
    was made for various combinations of distance and height.
    With data of this sort before him, coupled with the law of
    endurance described in the case of the pig-iron handlers, it
    is evident that the man who is directing shovelers can first
    teach them the exact methods which should be employed to
    use their strength to the very best advantage, and can then
    assign them daily tasks which are so just that the workman
    can each day be sure of earning the large bonus which is
    paid whenever he successfully performs this task.

    There were about 600 shovelers and laborers of this general
    class in the yard of the Bethlehem Steel Company at this
    time. These men were scattered in their work over a yard
    which was, roughly, about two miles long and half a mile
    wide. In order that each workman should be given his
    proper implement and his proper instructions for doing each
    new job, it was necessary to establish a detailed system for
    directing men in their work, in place of the old plan of
    handling them in large groups, or gangs, under a few yard
    foremen. As each workman came into the works in the
    morning, he took out of his own special pigeonhole, with his
    number on the outside, two pieces of paper, one of which
    stated just what implements he was to get from the tool
    room and where he was to start to work, and the second of
    which gave the history of his previous day’s work; that is, a
    statement of the work which he had done, how much he
    had earned the day before, etc. Many of these men were
    foreigners and unable to read and write, but they all knew
    at a glance the essence of this report, because yellow paper

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (20 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    showed the man that he had failed to do his full task the
    day before, and informed him that he had not earned as
    much as $1.85 a day, and that none but high-priced men
    would be allowed to stay permanently with this gang. The
    hope was further expressed that he would earn his full
    wages on the following day. So that whenever the men
    received white slips they knew that everything was all right,
    and whenever they received yellow slips they realized that
    they must do better or they would be shifted to some other
    class of work.

    Dealing with every workman as a separate individual in this
    way involved the building of a labor office for the
    superintendent and clerks who were in charge of this
    section of the work. In this office every laborer’s work was
    planned out well in advance, and the workmen were all
    moved from place to place by the clerks with elaborate
    diagrams or maps of the yard before them, very much as
    chessmen are moved on a chess-board, a telephone and
    messenger system having been installed for this purpose. In
    this way a large amount of the time lost through having too
    many men in one place and too few in another, and through
    waiting between jobs, was entirely eliminated. Under the
    old system the workmen were kept day after day in
    comparatively large gangs, each under a single foreman,
    and the gang was apt to remain of pretty nearly the same
    size whether there was much or little of the particular kind
    of work on hand which this foreman had under his charge,
    since each gang had to be kept large enough to handle
    whatever work in its special line was likely to come along.

    When one ceases to deal with men in large gangs or groups,
    and proceeds to study each workman as an individual, if the
    workman fails to do his task, some competent teacher
    should be sent to show him exactly how his work can best
    be done, to guide, help, and encourage him, and, at the
    same time, to study his possibilities as a workman. So that,
    under the plan which individualizes each workman, instead
    of brutally discharging the man or lowering his wages for
    failing to make good at once, he is given the time and the
    help required to make him proficient at his present job, or
    he is shifted to another class of work for which he is either
    mentally or physically better suited.

    All of this requires the kindly cooperation of the
    management, and involves a much more elaborate
    organization and system than the old-fashioned herding of
    men in large gangs. This organization consisted, in this
    case, of one set of men, who were engaged in the
    development of the science of laboring through time study,
    such as has been described above; another set of men,
    mostly skilled laborers themselves, who were teachers, and
    who helped and guided the men in their work; another set
    of tool-room men who provided them with the proper
    implements and kept them in perfect order, and another set
    of clerks who planned the work well in advance, moved the

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (21 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    men with the least loss of time from one place to another,
    and properly recorded each man’s earnings, etc. And this
    furnishes an elementary illustration of what has been
    referred to as cooperation between the management and
    the workmen.

    The question which naturally presents itself is whether an
    elaborate organization of this sort can be made to pay for
    itself; whether such an organization is not top-heavy. This
    question will best be answered by a statement of the results
    of the third year of working under this plan.

    Old Plan
    New Plan Task

    Work

    The number of yard laborers
    was reduced

    from 400-600 down to 140

    Average number of tons per
    man per day

    16 59

    Average earnings per man
    per day

    $1.15 $1.88

    Average cost of handling a
    ton of 2240 lbs

    $0.072 $0.033

    And in computing the low cost of $0.033 per ton, the office
    and tool-room expenses, and the wages of all labor
    superintendents, foremen, clerks, time-study men, etc., are
    included.

    During this year the total saving of the new plan over the
    old amounted to $36,417.69, and during the six months
    following, when all of the work of the yard was on task
    work, the saving was at the rate of between $75,000 and
    $80,000 per year.

    Perhaps the most important of all the results attained was
    the effect on the workmen themselves. A careful inquiry
    into the condition of these men developed the fact that out
    of the 140 workmen only two were said to be drinking men.
    This does not, of course, imply that many of them did not
    take an occasional drink. The fact is that a steady drinker
    would find it almost impossible to keep up with the pace
    which was set, so that they were practically all sober. Many,
    if not most of them, were saving money, and they all lived
    better than they had before. These men constituted the
    finest body of picked laborers that the writer has ever seen
    together, and they looked upon the men who were over
    them, their bosses and their teachers, as their very best
    friends; not as nigger drivers, forcing them to work extra
    hard for ordinary wages, but as friends who were teaching
    them and helping them to earn much higher wages than
    they had ever earned before.

    It would have been absolutely impossible for any one to

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (22 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    have stirred up strife between these men and their
    employers. And this presents a very simple though effective
    illustration of what is meant by the words “prosperity for
    the employee, coupled with prosperity for the employer,”
    the two principal objects of management. It is evident also
    that this result has been brought about by the application of
    the four fundamental principles of scientific management.

    As another illustration of the value of a scientific study of
    the motives which influence workmen in their daily work,
    the loss of ambition and initiative will be cited, which takes
    place in workmen when they are herded into gangs instead
    of being treated as separate individuals. A careful analysis
    had demonstrated the fact that when workmen are herded
    together in gangs, each man in the gang becomes far less
    efficient than when his personal ambition is stimulated; that
    when men work in gangs, their individual efficiency falls
    almost invariably down to or below the level of the worst
    man in the gang; and that they are all pulled down instead
    of being elevated by being herded together. For this reason
    a general order had been issued in the Bethlehem Steel
    Works that not more than four men were to be allowed to
    work in a labor gang without a special permit, signed by the
    General Superintendent of the works, this special permit to
    extend for one week only. It was arranged that as far as
    possible each laborer should be given a separate individual
    task. As there were about 5000 men at work in the
    establishment, the General Superintendent had so much to
    do that there was but little time left for signing these special
    permits.

    After gang work had been by this means broken up, an
    unusually fine set of ore shovelers had been developed,
    through careful selection and individual, scientific training.
    Each of these men was given a separate car to unload each
    day, and his wages depended upon his own personal work.
    The man who unloaded the largest amount of ore was paid
    the highest wages, and an unusual opportunity came for
    demonstrating the importance of individualizing each
    workman. Much of this ore came from the Lake Superior
    region, and the same ore was delivered both in Pittsburgh
    and in Bethlehem in exactly similar cars. There was a
    shortage of ore handlers in Pittsburgh, and hearing of the
    fine gang of laborers that had been developed at
    Bethlehem, one of the Pittsburgh steel works sent an agent
    to hire the Bethlehem men. The Pittsburgh men offered 4
    9/10 cents a ton for unloading exactly the same ore, with
    the same shovels, from the same cars, that were unloaded
    in Bethlehem for 3 2/10 cents a ton. After carefully
    considering this situation, it was decided that it would be
    unwise to pay more than 3 2/10 cents per ton for unloading
    the Bethlehem cars, because, at this rate, the Bethlehem
    laborers were earning a little over $1.85 per man per day,
    and this price was 60 per cent more than the ruling rate of
    wages around Bethlehem.

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (23 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    A long series of experiments, coupled with close
    observation, had demonstrated the fact that when workmen
    of this caliber are given a carefully measured task, which
    calls for a big day’s work on their part, and that when in
    return for this extra effort they are paid wages up to 60 per
    cent beyond the wages usually paid, that this increase in
    wages tends to make them not only more thrifty but better
    men in every way; that they live rather better, begin to
    save money, become more sober, and work more steadily.
    When, on the other hand, they receive much more than a
    60 per cent increase in wages, many of them will work
    irregularly and tend to become more or less shiftless,
    extravagant, and dissipated. Our experiments showed, in
    other words, that it does not do for most men to get rich
    too fast.

    After deciding, for this reason, not to raise the wages of our
    ore handlers, these men were brought into the office one at
    a time, and talked to somewhat as follows:

    “Now, Patrick, you have proved to us that you are a high-
    priced man. You have been earning every day a little more
    than $1.85, and you are just the sort of man that we want
    to have in our ore-shoveling gang. A man has come here
    from Pittsburgh, ho is offering 4 9/10 cents per ton for
    handling ore while we can pay only 3 9/10 cents per ton. I
    think, therefore, that you had better apply to this man for a
    job. Of course, you know we are very sorry to have you
    leave us, but you have proved yourself a high-priced man,
    and we are very glad to see you get this chance of earning
    more money. Just remember, however, that at any time in
    the future, when you get out of a job, you can always come
    right back to us. There will always be a job for a high-priced
    man like you in our gang here.”

    Almost all of the ore handlers took this advice, and went to
    Pittsburgh, but in about six weeks most of them were again
    back in Bethlehem unloading ore at the old rate of 3 2/10
    cents a ton. The writer had the following talk with one of
    these men after he had returned:

    “Patrick, what are you doing back here? I thought we had
    gotten rid of you.”

    “‘Well, Sir, I’ll tell you how it was. When we got out there
    Jimmy and I were put on to a car with eight other men. We
    started to shovel the ore out just the same as we do here.
    After about half an hour I saw a little devil alongside of me
    doing pretty near nothing, so I said to him, ‘Why don’t you
    go to work? Unless we get the ore out of this car we won’t
    get any money on pay-day.’ He turned to me and said,
    ‘Who in —— are you?’

    “‘Well,’ I said, ‘that’s none of your business’; and the little
    devil stood up to me and said, ‘You’ll be minding your own
    business, or I’ll throw you off this car!’ ‘Well, I could have

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (24 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    spit on him and drowned him, but the rest of the men put
    down their shovels and looked as if they were going to back
    him up; so I went round to Jimmy and said (so that the
    whole gang could hear it), ‘Now, Jimmy, you and I will
    throw a shovel full whenever this little devil throws one, and
    not another shovel full.’ So we watched him, and only
    shoveled when he shoveled.

    “When pay-day came around, though, we had less money
    than we got here at Bethlehem. After that Jimmy and I
    went in to the boss, and asked him for a car to ourselves,
    the same as we got at Bethlehem, but he told us to mind
    our own business. And when another pay-day came around
    we had less money than we got here at Bethlehem, so
    Jimmy and I got the gang together and brought them all
    back here to work again.”

    When working each man for himself, these men were able
    to earn higher wages at 3 2/10 cents a ton than they could
    earn when they were paid 4 9/10 cents a ton on gang work;
    and this again shows the great gain which results from
    working according to even the most elementary of scientific
    principles. But it also shows that in the application of the
    most elementary principles it is necessary for the
    management to do their share of the work in cooperating
    with the workmen. The Pittsburgh managers knew just how
    the results had been attained at Bethlehem, but they were
    unwilling to go to the small trouble and expense required to
    plan ahead and assign a separate car to each shoveler, and
    then keep an individual record of each man’s work, and pay
    him just what he had earned.

    Bricklaying is one of the oldest of our trades.

    For hundreds of years there has been little or no
    improvement made in the implements and materials used in
    this trade, nor in fact in the method of laying bricks. In spite
    of the millions of men who have practiced this trade, no
    great improvement has been evolved for many generations.
    Here, then, at least one would expect to find but little gain
    possible through scientific analysis and study. Mr. Frank B.
    Gilbreth, a member of our Society, who had himself studied
    bricklaying in his youth, became interested in the principles
    of scientific management, and decided to apply them to the
    art of bricklaying. He made an intensely interesting analysis
    and study of each movement of the bricklayer, and one
    after another eliminated all unnecessary movements and
    substituted fast for slow motions. He experimented with
    every minute element which in any way affects the speed
    and the tiring of the bricklayer.

    He developed the exact position which each of the feet of
    the bricklayer should occupy with relation to the wall, the
    mortar box, and the pile of bricks, and so made it
    unnecessary for him to take a step or two toward the pile of
    bricks and back again each time a brick is laid.

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (25 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    He studied the best height for the mortar box and brick pile,
    and then designed a scaffold, with a table on it, upon which
    all of the materials are placed, so as to keep the bricks, the
    mortar, the man, and the wall in their proper relative
    positions. These scaffolds are adjusted, as the wall grows in
    height, for all of the bricklayers by a laborer especially
    detailed for this purpose, and by this means the bricklayer
    is saved the exertion of stooping down to the level of his
    feet for each brick and each trowel full of mortar and then
    straightening up again. Think of the waste of effort that has
    gone on through all these years, with each bricklayer
    lowering his body, weighing, say, 150 pounds, down two
    feet and raising it up again every time a brick (weighing
    about 5 pounds) is laid in the wall! And this each bricklayer
    did about one thousand times a day.

    As a result of further study, after the bricks are unloaded
    from the cars, and before bringing them to the bricklayer,
    they are carefully sorted by a laborer, and placed with their
    best edge up on a simple wooden frame, constructed so as
    to enable him to take hold of each brick in the quickest time
    and in the most advantageous position. In this way the
    bricklayer avoids either having to turn the brick over or end
    for end to examine it before laying it, and he saves, also,
    the time taken in deciding which is the best edge and end to
    place on the outside of the wall. In most cases, also, he
    saves the time taken in disentangling the brick from a
    disorderly pile on the scaffold. This “pack” of bricks (as Mr.
    Gilbreth calls his loaded wooden frames) is placed by the
    helper in its proper position on the adjustable scaffold close
    to the mortar box.

    We have all been used to seeing bricklayers tap each brick
    after it is placed on its bed of mortar several times with the
    end of the handle of the trowel so as to secure the right
    thickness for the joint. Mr. Gilbreth found that by tempering
    the mortar just right, the bricks could be readily bedded to
    the proper depth by a downward pressure of the hand with
    which they are laid. He insisted that his mortar mixers
    should give special attention to tempering the mortar, and
    so save the time consumed in tapping the brick.

    Through all of this minute study of the motions to be made
    by the bricklayer in laying bricks under standard conditions,
    Mr. Gilbreth has reduced his movements from eighteen
    motions per brick to five, and even in one case to as low as
    two motions per brick. He has given all of the details of this
    analysis to the profession in the chapter headed “Motion
    Study,” of his book entitled “Bricklaying System,” published
    by Myron C. Clerk Publishing Company, New York and
    Chicago; E. F. N. Spon, of London.

    An analysis of the expedients used by Mr. Gilbreth in
    reducing the motions of his bricklayers from eighteen to five
    shows that this improvement has been made in three

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (26 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    different ways:

    First. He has entirely dispensed with certain movements
    which the bricklayers in the past believed were necessary,
    but which a careful study and trial on his part have shown
    to be useless.

    Second. He has introduced simple apparatus, such as his
    adjustable scaffold and his packets for holding the bricks, by
    means of which, with a very small amount of cooperation
    from a cheap laborer, he entirely eliminates a lot of
    tiresome and time-consuming motions which are necessary
    for the brick-layer who lacks the scaffold and the packet.

    Third. He teaches his bricklayers to make simple motions
    with both hands at the same time, where before they
    completed a motion with the right hand and followed it later
    with one from the left hand.

    For example, Mr. Gilbreth teaches his brick-layer to pick up
    a brick in the left hand at the same instant that he takes a
    trowel full of mortar with the right hand. This work with two
    hands at the same time is, of course, made possible by
    substituting a deep mortar box for the old mortar board (on
    which the mortar spread out so thin that a step or two had
    to be taken to reach it) and then placing the mortar box and
    the brick pile close together, and at the proper height on his
    new scaffold.

    These three kinds of improvements are typical of the ways
    in which needless motions can be entirely eliminated and
    quicker types of movements substituted for slow
    movements when scientific motion study, as Mr. Gilbreth
    calls his analysis, time study, as the writer has called similar
    work, are, applied in any trade.

    Most practical men would (knowing the opposition of almost
    all tradesmen to making any change in their methods and
    habits), however, be skeptical as to the possibility of
    actually achieving any large results from a study of this
    sort. Mr. Gilbreth reports that a few months ago, in a large
    brick building which he erected, he demonstrated on a
    commercial scale the great gain which is possible from
    practically applying his scientific study. With union
    bricklayers, in laying a factory wall, twelve inches thick,
    with two kinds of brick, faced and ruled joints on both sides
    of the wall, he averaged, after his selected workmen had
    become skilful in his new methods, 350 bricks per man per
    hour; whereas the average speed of doing this work with
    the old methods was, in that section of the country, 120
    bricks per man per hour. His bricklayers were taught his
    new method of bricklaying by their foreman. Those who
    failed to profit by their teaching were dropped, and each
    man, as he became proficient under the new method,
    received a substantial (not a small) increase in his wages.
    With a view to individualizing his workmen and stimulating

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (27 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    each man to do his best, Mr. Gilbreth also developed an
    ingenious method for measuring and recording the number
    of bricks laid by each man, and for telling each workman at
    frequent intervals how many bricks he had succeeded in
    laying.

    It is only when this work is compared with the conditions
    which prevail under the tyranny of some of our misguided
    bricklayers’ unions that the great waste of human effort
    which is going on will be realized. In one foreign city the
    bricklayers’ union have restricted their men to 275 bricks
    per day on work of this character when working for the city,
    and 375 per day when working for private owners. The
    members of this union are probably sincere in their belief
    that this restriction of output is a benefit to their trade. It
    should be plain to all men, however, that this deliberate
    loafing is almost criminal, in that it inevitably results in
    making every workman’s family pay higher rent for their
    housing, and also in the end drives work and trade away
    from their city, instead of bringing it to it.

    Why is it, in a trade which has been continually practiced
    since before the Christian era, and with implements
    practically the same as they now are, that this simplification
    of the bricklayer’s movements, this great gain, has not been
    made before?

    It is highly likely that many times during all of these years
    individual bricklayers have recognized the possibility of
    eliminating each of these unnecessary motions. But even if,
    in the past, he did invent each one of Mr. Gilbreth’s
    improvements, no bricklayer could alone increase his speed
    through their adoption because it will be remembered that
    in all cases several bricklayers work together in a row and
    that the walls all around a building must grow at the same
    rate of speed. No one bricklayer, then, can work much
    faster than the one next to him. Nor has any one workman
    the authority to make other men cooperate with him to do
    faster work. It is only through enforced standardization of
    methods, enforced adoption of the best implements and
    working conditions, and enforced cooperation that this
    faster work can be assured. And the duty of enforcing the
    adoption of standards and of enforcing-this cooperation
    rests with the management alone. The management must
    supply continually one or more teachers to show each new
    man the new and simpler motions, and the slower men
    must be constantly watched and helped until they have
    risen to their proper speed. All of those who, after proper
    teaching, either will not or cannot work in accordance with
    the new methods and at the higher speed must be
    discharged by the management. The management must
    also recognize the broad fact that workmen will not submit
    to this more rigid standardization and will not work extra
    hard, unless they receive extra pay for doing it.

    All of this involves an individual study of and treatment for

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (28 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    each man, while in the past they have been handled in large
    groups.

    The management must also see that those who prepare the
    bricks and the mortar and adjust the scaffold, etc., for the
    bricklayers, cooperate with them by doing their work just
    right and always on time; and they must also inform each
    bricklayer at frequent intervals as to the progress he is
    making, so that he may not unintentionally fall off in his
    pace. Thus it will be seen that it is the assumption by the
    management of new duties and new kinds of work never
    done by employers in the past that makes this great
    improvement possible, and that, without this new help from
    the management, the workman even with full knowledge of
    the new methods and with the best of intentions could not
    attain these startling results.

    Mr. Gilbreth’s method of bricklaying furnishes a simple
    illustration of true and effective cooperation. Not the type of
    cooperation in which a mass of workmen on one side
    together cooperate with the management; but that in which
    several men in the management (each one in his own
    particular way) help each workman individually, on the one
    hand, by studying his needs and his shortcomings and
    teaching him better and quicker methods, and, on the other
    hand, by seeing that all other workmen with whom he
    comes in contact help and cooperate with him by doing their
    part of the work right and fast.

    The writer has gone thus fully into Mr. Gilbreth’s method in
    order that it may be perfectly clear that this increase in
    output and that this harmony could not have been attained
    under the management of “initiative and incentive” (that is,
    by putting the problem up to the workman and leaving him
    to solve it alone) which has been the philosophy of the past.
    And that his success has been due to the use of the four
    elements which constitute the essence of scientific
    management.

    First. The development (by the management, not the
    workman) of the science of bricklaying, with rigid rules for
    each motion of every man, and the perfection and
    standardization of all implements and working conditions.

    Second. The careful selection and subsequent training of the
    bricklayers into first-class men, and the elimination of all
    men who refuse to or are unable to adopt the best methods.

    Third. Bringing the first-class bricklayer and the science of
    bricklaying together, through the constant help and
    watchfulness of the management, and through paying each
    man a large daily bonus for working fast and doing what he
    is told to do.

    Fourth. An almost equal division of the work and

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (29 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    responsibility between the workman and the management.
    All day long the management work almost side by side with
    the men, helping, encouraging, and smoothing the way for
    them, while in the past they stood one side, gave the men
    but little help, and threw on to them almost the entire
    responsibility as to methods, implements, speed, and
    harmonious cooperation.

    Of these four elements, the first (the development of the
    science of bricklaying) is the most interesting and
    spectacular. Each of the three others is, however, quite as
    necessary for success.

    It must not be forgotten that back of all this, and directing
    it, there must be the optimistic, determined, and hard-
    working leader who can wait patiently as well as work.

    In most cases (particularly when the work to be done is
    intricate in its nature) the “development of the science” is
    the most important of the four great elements of the new
    management. There are instances, however, in which the
    “scientific selection of the workman” counts for more than
    anything else.

    A case of this type is well illustrated in the very simple
    though unusual work of inspecting bicycle

    balls.

    When the bicycle craze was at its height some years ago
    several million small balls made of hardened steel were
    used annually in bicycle bearings. And among the twenty or
    more operations used in making steel balls, perhaps the
    most important was that of inspecting them after final
    polishing so as to remove all fire-cracked or otherwise
    imperfect balls before boxing.

    The writer was given the task of systematizing the largest
    bicycle ball factory in this country. This company had been
    running for from eight to ten years on ordinary day work
    before he undertook its reorganization, so that the one
    hundred and twenty or more girls who were inspecting the
    balls were “old bands” and skilled at their jobs.

    It is impossible even in the most elementary work to change
    rapidly from the old independence of individual day work to
    scientific cooperation.

    In most cases, however, there exist certain imperfections in
    working conditions which can at once be improved with
    benefit to all concerned.

    In this instance it was found that the inspectors (girls) were
    working ten and one-half hours per day (with a Saturday
    half holiday.)

    Their work consisted briefly in placing a row of small

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (30 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    polished steel balls on the back of the left hand, in the
    crease between two of the fingers pressed together, and
    while they were rolled over and over, they were minutely
    examined in a strong light, and with the aid of a magnet
    held in the right hand, the defective balls were picked out
    and thrown into especial boxes. Four kinds of defects were
    looked for-dented, soft, scratched, and fire-cracked–and
    they were mostly so minute as to be invisible to an eye not
    especially trained to this work. It required the closest
    attention and concentration, so that the nervous tension of
    the inspectors was considerable, in spite of the fact that
    they were comfortably seated and were not physically tired.

    A most casual study made it evident that a very
    considerable part of the ten and one-half hours during
    which the girls were supposed to work was really spent in
    idleness because the working period was too long. It is a
    matter of ordinary common sense to plan working hours so
    that the workers can really “work while they work” and
    “play while they play,” and not mix the two.

    Before the arrival of Mr. Sanford E. Thompson, who
    undertook a scientific study of the whole process, we
    decided, therefore, to shorten the working hours.

    The old foreman who had been over the inspecting room for
    years was instructed to interview one after another of the
    better inspectors and the more influential girls and persuade
    them that they could do just as much work in ten hours
    each day as they had been doing in ten and one-half hours.
    Each girl was told that the proposition was to shorten the
    day’s work to ten hours and pay them the same day’s pay
    they were receiving for the ten and one-half hours.

    In about two weeks the foreman reported that all of the
    girls he had talked to agreed that they could do their
    present work just as well in ten hours as in ten and one-half
    and that they approved of the change.

    The writer had not been especially noted for his tact so he
    decided that it would be wise for him to display a little more
    of this quality by having the girls vote on the new
    proposition. This decision was hardly justified, however, for
    when the vote was taken the girls were unanimous that 10
    1/2 hours was good enough for them and they wanted no
    innovation of any kind.

    This settled the matter for the time being. A few months
    later tact was thrown to the winds and the working hours
    were arbitrarily shortened in successive steps to 10 hours, 9
    1/2, 9, and 8 1/2 (the pay per day remaining the same);
    and with each shortening of the working day the output
    increased instead of diminishing.

    The change from the old to the scientific method in this

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (31 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    department was made under the direction of Mr. Sanford E.
    Thompson, perhaps the most experienced man in motion
    and time study in this country, under the general
    superintendence of Mr. H. L. Gantt.

    In the Physiological departments of our universities
    experiments are regularly conducted to determine what is
    known as the “personal coefficient” of the man tested. This
    is done by suddenly bringing some object, the letter A or B
    for instance, within the range of vision of the subject, who,
    the instant he recognizes the letter has to do some definite
    thing, such as to press a particular electric button. The time
    which elapses from the instant the letter comes in view until
    the subject presses the button is accurately recorded by a
    delicate scientific instrument.

    This test shows conclusively that there is a great difference
    in the “personal coefficient” of different men. Some
    individuals are born with unusually quick powers of
    perception accompanied by quick responsive action. With
    some the message is almost instantly transmitted from the
    eye to the brain, and the brain equally quickly responds by
    sending the proper message to the hand.

    Men of this type are said to have a low “personal
    coefficient,” while those of slow perception and slow action
    have a high “personal coefficient.”

    Mr. Thompson soon recognized that the quality most
    needed for bicycle ball inspectors was a low personal
    coefficient. Of course the ordinary qualities of endurance
    and industry were also called for.

    For the ultimate good of the girls as well as the company,
    however, it became necessary to exclude, all girls who
    lacked a low “personal coefficient.” And unfortunately this
    involved laying off many of the most intelligent, hardest
    working, and most trustworthy girls merely because they
    did not possess the quality of quick perception followed by
    quick action.

    While the gradual selection of girls was going on other
    changes were also being made.

    One of the dangers to be guarded against, when the pay of
    the man or woman is made in any way to depend on the
    quantity of the work done, is that in the effort to increase
    the quantity the quality is apt to deteriorate.

    It is necessary in almost all cases, therefore, to take
    definite steps to insure against any falling off in quality
    before moving in any way towards an increase in quantity.

    In the work of these particular girls quality was the very
    essence. They were engaged in picking out all defective

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (32 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management
    balls.

    The first step, therefore, was to make it impossible for them
    to slight their work without being, found out. This was
    accomplished through what is known as over-inspection,
    Each one of four of the most trust-worthy girls was given
    each day a lot of balls to inspect which had been examined
    the day before by one of the regular inspectors; the number
    identifying the lot to be over-inspected having been
    changed by the foreman so that none of the over-inspectors
    knew whose work they were examining. In addition to this
    one of the lots inspected by the four over-inspectors was
    examined on the following day by the chief inspector,
    selected on account of her especial accuracy and integrity.

    An effective expedient was adopted for checking the
    honesty and accuracy of the over-inspection. Every two or
    three days a lot of balls was especially prepared by the
    foreman, who counted out a definite number of perfect
    balls, and added a recorded number of defective balls of
    each kind. Neither the inspectors nor the over-inspectors
    had any means of distinguishing this prepared lot from the
    regular commercial lots. And in this way all temptation to
    slight their work or make false returns was removed.

    After insuring in this way against deterioration in quality,
    effective means were at once adopted to increase the
    output. Improved day work was substituted for the old
    slipshod method. An accurate daily record was kept both as
    to the quantity and quality of the work done in order to
    guard against any personal prejudice on the part of the
    foreman and to insure absolute impartiality and justice for
    each inspector. In a comparatively short time this record
    enabled the foreman to stir the ambition of all the
    inspectors by increasing the wages of those who turned out
    a large quantity and good quality, while at the same time
    lowering the pay of those who did indifferent work and
    discharging others who proved to be incorrigibly slow or
    careless. A careful examination was then made of the way
    in which each girl spent her time and an accurate time
    study was undertaken, through the use of a stop-watch and
    record blanks, to determine how fast each kind of inspection
    should be done, and to establish the exact conditions under
    which each girl could do her quickest and best work, while
    at the same time guarding against giving her a task so
    severe that there was danger from over fatigue or
    exhaustion. This investigation showed that the girls spent a
    considerable part of their time either in partial idleness,
    talking and half working, or in actually doing nothing.

    Even when the hours of labor had been shortened from 10
    1/2 to 8 1/2 hours a close observation of the girls showed
    that after about an hour and one-half of consecutive work
    they began to get nervous. They evidently needed a rest. It
    is wise to stop short of the point at which overstrain begins,
    so we arranged for them to have a ten minutes period for

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (33 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    recreation at the end of each hour and one quarter. During
    these recess periods (two of ten minutes each in the
    morning and two in the afternoon) they were obliged to
    stop work and were encouraged to leave their seats and get
    a complete change of occupation by walking around and
    talking, etc.

    In one respect no doubt some people will say that these
    girls were brutally treated. They were seated so far apart
    that they could not conveniently talk while at work.

    Shortening their hours of labor, however, and providing so
    far as we knew the most favorable working conditions made
    it possible for them to really work steadily instead of
    pretending to do so.

    And it is only after this stage in the reorganization is
    reached, when the girls have been properly selected and on
    the one hand such precautions have been taken as to guard
    against the possibility of over-driving them, while, on the
    other hand, the temptation to slight their work has been
    removed and the most favorable working conditions have
    been established, that the final step should be taken which
    insures them what they most want, namely, high wages,
    and the employers what they most want, namely, the
    maximum output and best quality of work, -which means a
    low labor cost.

    This step is to give each girl each day a carefully measured
    task which demands a full day’s work from a competent
    operative, and also to give her a large premium or bonus
    whenever she accomplishes this task.

    This was done in this case through establishing what is
    known as differential rate piece work. Under this system the
    pay of each girl was increased in proportion to the quantity
    of her output and also still more in proportion to the
    accuracy of her work.

    As will be shown later, the differential rate (the lots
    inspected by the over-inspectors forming the basis for the
    differential) resulted in a large gain in the quantity of work
    done and at the same time in a marked improvement in the
    quality.

    Before they finally worked to the best advantage it was
    found to be necessary to measure the output of each girl as
    often as once every hour, and to send a teacher to each
    individual who was found to be falling behind to find what
    was wrong, to straighten her out, and to encourage and
    help her to catch up.

    There is a general principle back of this which should be
    appreciated by all of those who are especially interested in
    the management of men.

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (34 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    A reward, if it is to be effective in stimulating men to do
    their best work, must come soon after the work has been
    done. But few men are able to look forward for more than a
    week or perhaps at most a month, and work hard for a
    reward which they are to receive at the end of this time.

    The average workman must be able to measure what he
    has accomplished and clearly see his reward at the end of
    each day if he is to do his best. And more elementary
    characters, such as the young girls inspecting bicycle balls,
    or children, for instance, should have proper
    encouragement either in the shape of personal attention
    from those over them or an actual reward in sight as often
    as once an hour.

    This is one of the principal reasons why cooperation or
    “profit-sharing” either through selling stock to the
    employees or through dividends on wages received at the
    end of the year, etc., have been at the best only mildly
    effective in stimulating men to work hard. The nice time
    which they are sure to have to-day if they take things easily
    and go slowly proves more attractive than steady hard work
    with a possible reward to be shared with others six months
    later. A second reason for the inefficiency of profit-sharing
    schemes had been that no form of cooperation has yet been
    devised in which each individual is allowed free scope for his
    personal ambition. Personal ambition always has been and
    will remain a more powerful incentive to exertion than a
    desire for the general welfare. The few misplaced drones,
    who do the loafing and share equally in the profits, with the
    rest, under cooperation are sure to drag the better men
    down toward their level.

    Other and formidable difficulties in the path of cooperative
    schemes are, the equitable division of the profits, and the
    fact that, while workmen are always ready to share the
    profits, they are neither able nor willing to share the losses.
    Further than this, in many cases, it is neither right nor just
    that they should share either the profits or the losses, since
    these may be due in great part to causes entirely beyond
    their influence or control, and to which they do not
    contribute.

    To come back to the girls inspecting bicycle balls, however,
    the final outcome of all the changes was that thirty-five girls
    did the work formerly done by one hundred and twenty.
    And that the accuracy of the work at the higher speed was
    two-thirds greater than at the former slow speed.

    The good that came to the girls was, First. That they
    averaged from 80 to 100 per cent higher wages than they
    formerly received.

    Second. Their hours of labor were shortened from 10 1/2 to
    8 1/2 per day, with a Saturday half holiday. And they were

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (35 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    given four recreation periods properly distributed through
    the day, which made overworking impossible for a healthy
    girl.

    Third. Each girl was made to feel that she was the object of
    especial care and interest on the part of the management,
    and that if anything went wrong with her she could always
    have a helper and teacher in the management to lean upon.

    Fourth. All young women should be given two consecutive
    days of rest (with pay) each month, to be taken whenever
    they may choose. It is my impression that these girls were
    given this privilege, although I am not quite certain on this
    point.

    The benefits which came to the company from these
    changes were:

    First. A substantial improvement in the quality of the
    product.

    Second. A material reduction in the cost of inspection, in
    spite of the extra expense involved in clerk work, teachers,
    time study, over-inspectors, and in paying higher wages.

    Third. That the most friendly relations existed between the
    management and the employees, which rendered labor
    troubles of any kind or a strike impossible.

    These good results were brought about by many changes
    which substituted favorable for unfavorable working
    conditions. It should be appreciated, however, that the one
    element which did more than all of the others was, the
    careful selection of girls with quick perception to replace
    those whose perceptions were slow–(the substitution of
    girls with a low personal coefficient for those whose
    personal coefficient was high)–the scientific selection of the
    workers.

    The illustrations have thus far been purposely confined to
    the more elementary types of work, so that a very strong
    doubt must still remain as to whether this kind of
    cooperation is desirable in the case of more intelligent
    mechanics, that is, in the case of men who are more
    capable of generalization, and who would therefore be more
    likely, of their own volition, to choose the more scientific
    and better methods. The following illustrations will be given
    for the purpose of demonstrating the fact that in the higher
    classes of work the scientific laws which are developed are
    so intricate that the high-priced mechanic needs (even more
    than the cheap laborer) the cooperation of men better
    educated than himself in finding the laws, and then in
    selecting, developing, and training him to work in
    accordance with these laws. These illustrations should make
    perfectly clear our original proposition that in practically all

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (36 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    of the mechanic arts the science which underlies each
    workman’s act is so great and amounts to so much that the
    workman who is best suited to actually doing the work is
    incapable, either through lack of education or through
    insufficient mental capacity, of understanding this science.

    A doubt, for instance, will remain in the minds perhaps of
    most readers (in the case of an establishment which
    manufactures the same machine, year in and year out, in
    large quantities, and in which, therefore, each mechanic
    repeats the same limited series of operations over and over
    again), whether the ingenuity of each workman and the
    help which he from time to time receives from his foreman
    will not develop such superior methods and such a personal
    dexterity that no scientific study which could be made would
    result in a material increase in efficiency.

    A number of years ago a company employing about three
    hundred men, which had been manufacturing the same
    machine for ten to fifteen years, sent for us to report as to
    whether any gain could be made through the introduction of
    scientific management. Their shops had been run for many
    years under a good superintendent and with excellent
    foremen and workmen, on piece work. The whole
    establishment was, without doubt, in better physical
    condition than the average machine-shop in this country.
    The superintendent was distinctly displeased when told that
    through the adoption of task management the output, with
    the same number of men and machines, could be more than
    doubled. He said that he believed that any such statement
    was mere boasting, absolutely false, and instead of inspiring
    him with confidence, he was disgusted that any one should
    make such an impudent claim. He, however, readily
    assented to the proposition that he should select any one of
    the machines whose output he considered as representing
    the average of the shop, and that we should then
    demonstrate on this machine that through scientific
    methods its output could be more than doubled.

    The machine selected by him fairly represented the work of
    the shop. It had been run for ten or twelve years past by a
    first-class mechanic who was more than equal in his ability
    to the average workmen in the establishment. In a shop of
    this sort in which similar machines are made over and over
    again, the work is necessarily greatly subdivided, so that no
    one man works upon more than a comparatively small
    number of parts during the year. A careful record was
    therefore made, in the presence of both parties, ox the time
    actually taken in finishing each of the parts which this man
    worked upon. The total time required by him to finish each
    piece, as well as the exact speeds and feeds which he took,
    were noted and a record was kept of the time which he took
    in setting the work in the machine and removing it. After
    obtaining in this way a statement of what represented a fair
    average of the work done in the shop, we applied to this
    one machine the principles of scientific management.

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (37 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    By means of four quite elaborate slide-rules, which have
    been especially made for the purpose of determining the all-
    round capacity of metal-cutting machines, a careful analysis
    was made of every element of this machine in its relation to
    the work in hand. Its Pulling power at its various speeds, its
    feeding capacity, and its proper speeds were determined by
    means of the slide-rules, and changes were then made in
    the countershaft and driving pulleys so as to run it at its
    proper speed. Tools, made of high-speed steel, and of the
    proper shapes, were properly dressed, treated, and ground.
    (It should be understood, however, that in this case the
    high-speed steel which had heretofore been in general use
    in the shop was also used in our demonstration.) A large
    special slide-rule was then made, by means of which the
    exact speeds and feeds were indicated at which each kind of
    work could be done in the shortest possible time in this
    particular lathe. After preparing in this way so that the
    workman should work according to the new method, one
    after another, pieces of work were finished in the lathe,
    corresponding to the work which had been done in our
    preliminary trials, and the gain in time made through
    running the machine according to scientific principles
    ranged from two and one-half times the speed in the
    slowest instance to nine times the speed in the highest.

    The change from rule-of-thumb management to scientific
    management involves, however, not only a study of what is
    the proper speed for doing the work and a remodeling of
    the tools and the implements in the shop, but also a
    complete change in the mental attitude of all the men in the
    shop toward their work and toward their employers. The
    physical improvements in the machines necessary to insure
    large gains, and the motion, study followed by minute study
    with a stop-watch of the time in which each workman
    should do his work, can be made comparatively quickly. But
    the change in the mental attitude and in the habits of the
    three hundred or more workmen can be brought about only
    slowly and through a long series of object-lessons, which
    finally demonstrates to each man the great advantage
    which he will gain by heartily cooperating in his every-day
    work with the men in the management. Within three years,
    however, in this shop, the output had been more than
    doubled per man and per machine. The men had been
    carefully selected and in almost all cases promoted from a
    lower to a higher order of work, and so instructed by their
    teachers (the functional foremen) that they were able to
    earn higher wages than ever before. The average increase
    in the daily earnings of each man was about 35 per cent.,
    while, at the same time, the sum total of the wages paid for
    doing a given amount of work was lower than before. This
    increase in the speed of doing the work, of course, involved
    a substitution of the quickest hand methods for the old
    independent rule-of-thumb methods, and an elaborate
    analysis of the hand work done by each man. (By hand
    work is meant such work as depends upon the manual
    dexterity and speed of a workman, and which is

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (38 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    independent of the work done by the machine.) The time
    saved by scientific hand work was in many cases greater
    even than that saved in machine-work.

    It seems important to fully explain the reason why, with the
    aid of a slide-rule, and after having studied the art of
    cutting metals, it was possible for the scientifically equipped
    man, who had never before seen these particular jobs, and
    who had never worked on this machine, to do work from
    two and one-half to nine times as fast as it had been done
    before by a good mechanic who had spent his whole time
    for some ten to twelve years in doing this very work upon
    this particular machine. In a word, this was possible
    because the art of cutting metals involves a true science of
    no small magnitude, a science, in fact, so intricate that it is
    impossible for any machinist who is suited to running a
    lathe year in and year out either to understand it or to work
    according to its laws without the help of men who have
    made this their specialty. Men who are un-familiar with
    machine-shop work are prone to look upon the manufacture
    of each piece as a special problem, independent of any
    other kind of machine-work. They are apt to think, for
    instance, that the problems connected with making the
    parts of an engine require the especial study, one may say
    almost the life study, of a set of engine-making mechanics,
    and that these problems are entirely different from those
    which would be met with in machining lathe or planer parts.
    In fact, however, a study of those elements which are
    peculiar either to engine parts or to lathe parts is trifling,
    compared with the great study of the art, or science, of
    cutting metals, upon a knowledge of which rests the ability
    to do really fast machine-work of all kinds.

    The real problem is how to remove chips fast from a casting
    or a forging, and how to make the piece smooth and true in
    the shortest time, and it matters but little whether the piece
    being worked upon is part, say, of a marine engine, a
    printing-press, or an automobile. For this reason, the man
    with the slide rule, familiar with the science of cutting
    metals, who had never before seen this particular work, was
    able completely to distance the skilled mechanic who had
    made the parts of this machine his specialty for years.

    It is true that whenever intelligent and educated men find
    that the responsibility for making progress in any of the
    mechanic arts rests with them, instead of upon the
    workmen who are actually laboring at the trade, that they
    almost invariably start on the road which leads to the
    development of a science where, in the past, has existed
    mere traditional or rule-of-thumb knowledge. When men,
    whose education has given them the habit of generalizing
    and everywhere looking for laws, find themselves
    confronted with a multitude of problems, such as exist in
    every trade and which have a general similarity one to
    another, it is inevitable that they should try to gather these
    problems into certain logical groups, and then search for

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (39 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    some general laws or rules to guide them in their solution.
    As has been pointed out, however, the underlying principles
    of the management of “initiative and incentive,” that is, the
    underlying philosophy of this management, necessarily
    leaves the solution of all of these problems in the hands of
    each individual workman, while the philosophy of scientific
    management places their solution in the hands of the
    management. The workman’s whole time is each day taken
    in actually doing the work with his hands, so that, even if he
    had the necessary education and habits of generalizing in
    his thought, he lacks the time and the opportunity for
    developing these laws, because the study of even a simple
    law involving say time study requires the cooperation of two
    men, the one doing the work while the other times him with
    a stop-watch. And even if the workman were to develop
    laws where before existed only rule-of-thumb knowledge,
    his personal interest would lead him almost inevitably to
    keep his discoveries secret, so that he could, by means of
    this special knowledge, personally do more work than other
    men and so obtain higher wages.

    Under scientific management, on the other hand, it
    becomes the duty and also the pleasure of those who are
    engaged in the management not only to develop laws to
    replace rule of thumb, but also to teach impartially all of the
    workmen who are under them the quickest ways of
    working. The useful results obtained from these laws are
    always so great that any company can well afford to pay for
    the time and the experiments needed to develop them.
    Thus under scientific management exact scientific
    knowledge and methods are everywhere, sooner or later,
    sure to replace rule of thumb, whereas under the old type of
    management working in accordance with scientific laws is
    an impossibility. The development of the art or science of
    cutting metals is an apt illustration of this fact. In the fall of
    1880, about the time that the writer started to make the
    experiments above referred to, to determine what
    constitutes a proper day’s work for a laborer, he also
    obtained the permission of Mr. William Sellers, the President
    of the Midvale Steel Company, to make a series of
    experiments to determine what angles and shapes of tools
    were the best for cutting steel, and also to try to determine
    the proper cutting speed for steel. At the time that these
    experiments were started it was his belief that they would
    not last longer than six months, and, in fact, if it had been
    known that a longer period than this would be required, the
    permission to spend a considerable sum of money in
    making them would not have been forthcoming.

    A 66-inch diameter vertical boring-mill was the first
    machine used in making these experiments, and large
    locomotive tires, made out of hard steel of uniform quality,
    were day after day cut up into chips in gradually learning
    how to make, shape, and use the cutting tools so that they
    would do faster work. At the end of six months sufficient
    practical information had been obtained to far more than

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (40 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    repay the cost of materials and wages which had been
    expended in experimenting. And yet the comparatively
    small number of experiments which had been made served
    principally to make it clear that the actual knowledge
    attained was but a small fraction of that which still remained
    to be developed, and which was badly needed by us, in our
    daily attempt to direct and help the machinists in their tasks.

    Experiments in this field were carried on, with occasional
    interruption, through a period of about 26 years, in the
    course of which ten different experimental machines were
    especially fitted up to do this work. Between 30,000 and
    50,000 experiments were carefully recorded, and many
    other experiments were made, of which no record was kept.
    In studying these laws more than 800,000 pounds of steel
    and iron was cut up into chips with the experimental tools,
    and it is estimated that from $150,000 to $200,000 was
    spent in the investigation.

    Work of this character is intensely interesting to any one
    who has any love for scientific research. For the purpose of
    this paper, however, it should be fully appreciated that the
    motive power which kept these experiments going through
    many years, and which supplied the money and the
    opportunity for their accomplishment, was not an abstract
    search after scientific knowledge, but was the very practical
    fact that we lacked the exact information which was needed
    every day, in order to help our machinists to do their work
    in the best way and in the quickest time.

    All of these experiments were made to enable us to answer
    correctly the two questions which face every machinist each
    time that he does a piece of work in a metal-cutting
    machine, such as a lathe, planer, drill press, or miring
    machine. These two questions are:

    In order to do the work in the quickest time, At what cutting
    speed shall I run my machine? and

    What feed shall I use?

    They sound so simple that they would appear to call for
    merely the trained judgment of any good mechanic. In fact,
    however, after working 26 years, it has been found that the
    answer in every case involves the solution of an intricate
    mathematical problem, in which the effect of twelve
    independent variables must be determined.

    Each of the twelve following variables has an important
    effect upon the answer. The figures which are given with
    each of the variables represent the effect of this element
    upon the cutting speed.

    For example, after the first variable (A) we quote,

    “The proportion is as I in the case of semi-hardened steel or
    chilled iron to 100 in the case of a very soft, low-carbon

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (41 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    steel.” The meaning of this quotation is that soft steel can
    be cut 100 times as fast as the hard steel or chilled iron.
    The ratios which are given, then, after each of these
    elements, indicate the wide range of judgment which
    practically every machinist has been called upon to exercise
    in the past in determining the best speed at which to run
    the machine and the best feed to use.

    (A) The quality of the metal which is to be cut; i.e., its
    hardness or other qualities which affect the cutting speed.
    The proportion is as 1 in the case of semi-hardened steel or
    chilled iron to 100 in the case of very soft, low-carbon steel.

    (B) The chemical composition of the steel from which the
    tool is made, and the heat treatment of the tool. The
    proportion is as 1 in tools made from tempered carbon steel
    to 7 in the best high-speed tools.

    (C) The thickness of the shaving, or, the thickness of the
    spiral strip or band of metal which is to be removed by the
    tool. The proportion is as 1 with thickness of shaving 3/16
    of an inch to 3 1/2 with thickness of shaving 1/64 of an inch.

    (D) The shape or contour of the cutting edge of the tool.
    The proportion is as 1 in a thread tool to 6 in a broad-nosed
    cutting tool.

    (E) Whether a copious stream of water or other cooling
    medium is used on the tool. The proportion is as 1 for tool
    running dry to 1.41 for tool cooled by a copious stream of
    water.

    (F) The depth of the cut. The proportion is as 1 with 1/2
    inch depth of cut to 1.36 with 1/8 inch depth of cut.

    (G) The duration of the cut, i.e., the time which a tool must
    last under pressure of the shaving without being reground.
    The proportion is as 1 when tool is to be ground every 1 1/2
    hours to 1.20 when tool is to be ground every 20 minutes.

    (H) The lip and clearance angles of the tool. The proportion
    is as 1 with lip angle of 68 degrees to 1.023 with lip angle of
    61 degrees.

    (J) The elasticity of the work and of the tool on account of
    producing chatter. The proportion is as 1 with tool
    chattering to 1.15 with tool running smoothly.

    (K) The diameter of the casting or forging which is being cut.

    (L) The pressure of the chip or shaving upon the cutting
    surface of the tool.

    (M) The pulling power and the speed and feed changes of

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (42 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    the machine.

    It may seem preposterous to many people that it should
    have required a period of 26 years to investigate the effect
    of these twelve variables upon the cutting speed of metals.
    To those, however, who have had personal experience as
    experimenters, it will be appreciated that the great difficulty
    of the problem lies in the fact that it contains so many
    variable elements. And in fact the great length of time
    consumed in making each single experiment was caused by
    the difficulty of holding eleven variables constant and
    uniform throughout the experiment, while the effect of the
    twelfth variable was being investigated. Holding the eleven
    variables constant was far more difficult than the
    investigation of the twelfth element.

    As, one after another, the effect upon the cutting speed of
    each of these variables was investigated, in order that
    practical use could be made of this knowledge, it was
    necessary to find a mathematical formula which expressed
    in concise form the laws which had been obtained. As
    examples of the twelve formulae which were developed, the
    three following are given:

    P = 45,000 D 14/15 F 3/4

    V = 90/T 1/8

    V = 11.9/ (F 0.665(48/3 D) 0.2373 + (2.4 / (18 + 24D))

    After these laws had been investigated and the various
    formulae which mathematically expressed them had been
    determined, there still remained the difficult task of how to
    solve one of these complicated mathematical problems
    quickly enough to make this knowledge available for every-
    day use. If a good mathematician who had these formula
    before Mm were to attempt to get the proper answer (i.e.,
    to get the correct cutting speed and feed by working in the
    ordinary way) it would take him from two to six hours, say,
    to solve a single problem; far longer to solve the
    mathematical problem than would be taken in most cases
    by the workmen in doing the whole job in his machine. Thus
    a task of considerable magnitude which faced us was that of
    finding a quick solution of this problem, and as we made
    progress in its solution, the whole problem was from time to
    time presented by the writer to one after another of the
    noted mathematicians in this country. They were offered
    any reasonable fee for a rapid, practical method to be used
    in its solution. Some of these men merely glanced at it;
    others, for the sake of being courteous, kept it before them
    for some two or three weeks. They all gave us practically
    the same answer: that in many cases it was possible to,
    solve mathematical problems which contained four
    variables, and in some cases problems with five or six
    variables, but that it was manifestly impossible to solve a
    problem containing twelve variables in any other way than

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (43 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    by the slow process of “trial and error.”

    A quick solution was, however, so much of a necessity in
    our every-day work of running machine-shops, that in spite
    of the small encouragement received from the
    mathematicians, we continued at irregular periods, through
    a term of fifteen years, to give a large amount of time
    searching for a simple solution. Four or five men at various
    periods gave practically their whole time to this work, and
    finally, while we were at the Bethlehem Steel Company, the
    slide-rule was developed which is illustrated on Folder No.
    11 of the paper “On the Art of Cutting Metals,” and is
    described in detail in the paper presented by Mr. Carl G.
    Barth to the American Society of Mechanical Engineers,
    entitled “Slide-rules for the Machine-shop, as a part of the
    Taylor System of Management” (Vol. XXV of The
    Transactions of the American Society of Mechanical
    Engineers). By means of this slide-rule, one of these
    intricate problems can be solved in less than a half minute
    by any good mechanics whether he understands anything
    about mathematics or not, thus making available for every-
    day, practical use the years of experimenting on the art of
    cutting metals. This is a good illustration of the fact that
    some way can always be found of making practical,
    everyday use of complicated scientific data, which appears
    to be beyond the experience and the range of the technical
    training of ordinary practical men. These slide-rules have
    been for years in constant daily use by machinists having no
    knowledge of mathematics.

    A glance at the intricate mathematical formula (see page
    109) which represent the laws of cutting metals should
    clearly show the reason why it is impossible for any
    machinist, without the aid of these laws, and who depends
    upon his personal experience, correctly to guess at the
    answer to the two questions,

    What speed shall I use?

    What feed shall I use?

    even though he may repeat the same piece of work many
    times.

    To return to the case of the machinist who had been
    working for ten to twelve years in machining the same
    pieces over and over again, there was but a remote chance
    in any of the various kinds of work which this man did that
    he should hit upon the one best method of doing each piece
    of work out of the hundreds of possible methods which lay
    before him. In considering this typical case, it must also be
    remembered that the metal-cutting machines throughout
    our machine-shops have practically all been speeded by
    their makers by guesswork, and without the knowledge
    obtained through a study of the art of cutting metals. In the
    machine-shops systematized by us we have found that

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (44 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    there is not one machine in a hundred which is speeded by
    its makers at anywhere near the correct cutting speed. So
    that, in order to compete with the science of cutting metals,
    the machinist, before he could use proper speeds, would
    first have to put new pulleys on the countershaft of his
    machine, and also make in most cases changes in the
    shapes and treatment of his tools, etc. Many of these
    changes are matters entirely beyond his control, even if he
    knows what ought to be done.

    If the reason is clear to the reader why the rule-of-thumb
    knowledge obtained by the machinist who is engaged on
    repeat work cannot possibly compete with the true science
    of cutting metals, it should be even more apparent why the
    high-class mechanic, who is called upon to do a great
    variety of work from day to day, is even less able to
    compete with this science. The high-class mechanic who
    does a different kind of work each day, in order to do each
    job in the quickest time, would need, in addition to a
    thorough knowledge of the art of cutting metals, a vast
    knowledge and experience in the quickest way of doing
    each kind of hand work. And the reader, by calling to mind
    the gain which was made by Mr. Gilbreth through his motion
    and time study in laying bricks, will appreciate the great
    possibilities for quicker methods of doing all kinds of hand
    work which lie before every tradesman after he has the help
    which comes from a scientific motion and time study of his
    work.

    For nearly thirty years past, time-study men connected with
    the management of machine-shops have been devoting
    their whole time to a scientific motion study, followed by
    accurate time study, with a stop-watch, of all of the
    elements connected with the machinist’s work. When,
    therefore, the teachers, who form one section of the
    management, and who are cooperating with the working
    men, are in possession both of the science of cutting metals
    and of the equally elaborate motion-study and time-study
    science connected with this work, it is not difficult to
    appreciate why even the highest class mechanic is unable to
    do his best work without constant daily assistance from his
    teachers. And if this fact has been made clear to the reader,
    one of the important objects in writing this paper will have
    been realized.

    It is hoped that the illustrations which have been given
    make it apparent why scientific management must
    inevitably in all cases produce overwhelmingly greater
    results, both for the company and its employees, than can
    be obtained with the management of “initiative and
    incentive.” And it should also be clear that these results
    have been attained, not through a marked superiority in the
    mechanism of one type of management over the
    mechanism of another, but rather through the substitution
    of one set of underlying principles for a totally different set
    of principles, by the substitution of one philosophy for

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (45 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    another philosophy in industrial management.

    To repeat then throughout all of these illustrations, it will be
    seen that the useful results have hinged mainly upon (1)
    the substitution of a science for the individual judgment of
    the workman; (2) the scientific selection and development
    of the workman, after each man has been studied, taught,
    and trained, and one may say experimented with, instead of
    allowing the workmen to select themselves and develop in a
    haphazard way; and (3) the intimate cooperation of the
    management with the workmen, so that they together do
    the work in accordance with the scientific laws which have
    been developed, instead of leaving the solution of each
    problem in the hands of the individual workman. In applying
    these new principles, in place of the old individual effort of
    each workman, both sides share almost equally in the daily
    performance of each task, the management doing that part
    of the work for which they are best fitted, and the workmen
    the balance.

    It is for the illustration of this philosophy that this paper has
    been written, but some of the elements involved in its
    general principles should be further discussed.

    The development of a science sounds like a formidable
    undertaking, and in fact anything like a thorough study of a
    science such as that of cutting metals necessarily involves
    many years of work. The science of cutting metals,
    however, represents in its complication, and in the time
    required to develop it, almost an extreme case in the
    mechanic arts. Yet even in this very intricate science, within
    a few months after starting, enough knowledge had been
    obtained to much more than pay for the work of
    experimenting. This holds true in the case of practically all
    scientific development in the mechanic arts. The first laws
    developed for cutting metals were crude, and contained
    only a partial knowledge of the truth, yet this imperfect
    knowledge was vastly better than the utter lack of exact
    information or the very imperfect rule of thumb which
    existed before, and it enabled the workmen, with the help
    of the management, to do far quicker and better work.

    For example, a very short time was needed to discover one
    or two types of tools which, though imperfect as compared
    with the shapes developed years afterward, were superior
    to all other shapes and kinds in common use. These tools
    were adopted as standard and made possible an immediate
    increase in the speed of every machinist who used them.
    These types were superseded in a comparatively short time
    by still other tools which remained standard until they in
    their turn made way for later improvements.

    The science which exists in most of the mechanic arts is,
    however, far simpler than the science of cutting metals. In
    almost all cases, in fact, the laws or rules which are
    developed are so simple that the average man would hardly

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (46 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    dignify them with the name of a science. In most trades,
    the science is developed through a comparatively simple
    analysis and time study of the movements required by the
    workmen to do some small part of his work, and this study
    is usually made by a man equipped merely with a stop-
    watch and a properly ruled notebook. Hundreds of these
    “time-study men” are now engaged in developing
    elementary scientific knowledge where before existed only
    rule of thumb. Even the motion study of Mr. Gilbreth in
    bricklaying (described on pages 77 to 84) involves a much
    more elaborate investigation than that which occurs in most
    cases. The general steps to be taken in developing a simple
    law of this class are as follows:

    First. Find, say, 10 or 15 different men (preferably in as
    many separate establishments and different parts of the
    country) who are especially skilful in doing the particular
    work to be analyzed.

    Second. Study the exact series of elementary operations or
    motions which each of these men uses in doing the work
    which is being investigated, as well as the implements each
    man uses.

    Third. Study with a stop-watch the time required to make
    each of these elementary movements and then select the
    quickest way of doing each element of the work.

    Fourth. Eliminate all false movements, slow movements,
    and useless movements.

    Fifth. After doing away with all unnecessary movements,
    collect into one series the quickest and best movements as
    well as the best implements.

    This one new method, involving that series of motions which
    can be made quickest and best, is then substituted in place
    of the ten or fifteen inferior series which were formerly in
    use. This best method becomes standard, and remains
    standard, to be taught first to the teachers (or functional
    foremen) and by them to every workman in the
    establishment until it is superseded by a quicker and better
    series of movements. In this simple way one element after
    another of the science is developed.

    In the same way each type of implement used in a trade is
    studied. Under the philosophy of the management of
    “initiative and incentive” each work-man is called upon to
    use his own best judgment, so as to do the work in the
    quickest time, and from this results in all cases a large
    variety in the shapes and types of implements which are
    used for any specific purpose. Scientific management
    requires, first, a careful investigation of each of the many
    modifications of the same implement, developed under rule
    of thumb; and second, after a time study has been made of

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (47 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    the speed attainable with each of these implements, that
    the good points of several of them shall be united in a single
    standard implement, which will enable the workman to work
    faster and with greater ease than he could before. This one
    implement, then, is adopted as standard in place of the
    many different kinds before in use, and it remains standard
    for all workmen to use until superseded by an implement
    which has been shown, through motion and time study, to
    be still better.

    With this explanation it will be seen that the development of
    a science to replace rule of thumb is in most cases by no
    means a formidable under-taking, and that it can be
    accomplished by ordinary, every-day men without any
    elaborate scientific training; but that, on the other hand, the
    successful use of even the simplest improvement of this
    kind calls for records, system, and cooperation where in the
    past existed only individual effort.

    There is another type of scientific investigation which has
    been referred to several times in this paper, and which
    should receive special attention, namely, the accurate study
    of the motives which influence men. At first it may appear
    that this is a matter for individual observation and
    judgment, and is not a proper subject for exact scientific
    experiments. It is true that the laws which result from
    experiments of this class, owing to the fact that the very
    complex organism–the human being–is being
    experimented with, are subject to a larger number of
    exceptions than is the case with laws relating to material
    things. And yet laws of this kind, which apply to a large
    majority of men, unquestionably exist, and when clearly
    defined are of great value as a guide in dealing with men. In
    developing these laws, accurate, carefully planned and
    executed experiments, extending through a term of years,
    have been made, similar in a general way to the
    experiments upon various other elements which have been
    referred to in this paper. Perhaps the most important law
    belonging to this class, in its relation to scientific
    management, is the effect which the task idea has upon the
    efficiency of the workman. This, in fact, has become such an
    important element of the mechanism of scientific
    management, that by a great number of people scientific
    management has come to be known as “task management.”

    There is absolutely nothing new in the task idea. Each one
    of us will remember that in his own case this idea was
    applied with good results in his school-boy days. No efficient
    teacher would think of giving a class of students an
    indefinite lesson to learn. Each day a definite, clear-cut task
    is set by the teacher before each scholar, stating that he
    must learn just so much of the subject; and it is only by this
    means that proper, systematic progress can be made by the
    students. The average boy would go very slowly if, instead
    of being given a task, he were told to do as much as he
    could. All of us are grown-up children, and it is equally true

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (48 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    that the average workman will work with the greatest
    satisfaction, both to himself and to his employer, when he is
    given each day a definite task which he is to perform in a
    given time, and which constitutes a proper day’s work for a
    good workman. This furnishes the workman with a clear-cut
    standard, by which he can throughout the day measure his
    own progress, and the accomplishment of which affords him
    the greatest satisfaction.

    The writer has described in other papers a series of
    experiments made upon workmen, which have resulted in
    demonstrating the fact that it is impossible, through any
    long period of time, to get work-men to work much harder
    than the average men around them, unless they are
    assured a large and a permanent increase in their pay. This
    series of experiments, however, also proved that plenty of
    workmen can be found who are willing to work at their best
    speed, provided they are given this liberal increase in
    wages. The workman must, however, be fully assured that
    this increase beyond the average is to be permanent. Our
    experiments have shown that the exact percentage of
    increase required to make a workman work at his highest
    speed depends upon the kind of work which the man is
    doing.

    It is absolutely necessary, then, when workmen are daily
    given a task which calls for a high rate of speed on their
    part, that they should also be insured the necessary high
    rate of pay whenever they are successful. This involves not
    only fixing for each man his daily task, but also paying him
    a large bonus, or premium, each time that he succeeds in
    doing his task in the given time. It is difficult to appreciate
    in full measure the help which the proper use of these two
    elements is to the workman in elevating him to the highest
    standard of efficiency and speed in his trade, and then
    keeping him there, unless one has seen first the old plan
    and afterward the new tried upon the same man. And in
    fact until one has seen similar accurate experiments made
    upon various grades of workmen engaged in doing widely
    different types of work. The remarkable and almost
    uniformly good results from the correct application of the
    task and the bonus must be seen to be appreciated.

    These two elements, the task and the bonus (which, as has
    been pointed out in previous papers, can be applied in
    several ways), constitute two of the most important
    elements of the mechanism of scientific management. They
    are especially important from the fact that they are, as it
    were, a climax, demanding before they can be used almost
    all of the other elements of the mechanism; such as a
    planning department, accurate time study, standardization
    of methods and implements, a routing system, the training
    of functional foremen or teachers, and in many cases
    instruction cards slide-rules, etc. (Referred to later in rather
    more detail on page 129.)

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (49 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    The necessity for systematically teaching workmen how to
    work to the best advantage has been several times referred
    to. It seems desirable, therefore, to explain in rather more
    detail how this teaching is done. In the case of a machine-
    shop which is managed under the modern system, detailed
    written instructions are the best way of doing each piece of
    work are prepared in advance, by men in the planning
    department. These instructions represent the combined
    work of several men in the planning room, each of whom
    has his own specialty, or function. One of them, for
    instance, is a specialist on the proper speeds and cutting
    tools to be used. He uses the slide-rules which have been
    above described as an aid, to guide him in obtaining proper
    speeds, etc. Another man analyzes the best and quickest
    motions to be made by the workman in setting the work up
    in the machine and removing it, etc. Still a third, through
    the time-study records which have been accumulated,
    makes out a timetable giving the proper speed for doing
    each element of the work. The directions of all of these
    men, however, are written on a single instruction card, or
    sheet.

    These men of necessity spend most of their time in the
    planning department, because they must be close to the
    records and data which they continually use in their work,
    and because this work requires the use of a desk and
    freedom from interruption. Human nature is such, however,
    that many of the workmen, if left to themselves, would pay
    but little attention to their written instructions. It is
    necessary, therefore, to provide teachers (called functional
    foremen) to see that the workmen both understand and
    carry out these written instructions.

    Under functional management, the old-fashioned single
    foreman is superseded by eight different men, each one of
    whom has his own special duties, and these men, acting as
    the agents for the planning department (see paragraph 234
    to 245 of the paper entitled “Shop Management”), are the
    expert teachers, who are at all times in the shop, helping,
    and directing the workmen. Being each one chosen for his
    knowledge and personal skill in his specialty, they are able
    not only to tell the workman what he should do, but in case
    of necessity they do the work themselves in the presence of
    the workman, so as to show him not only the best but also
    the quickest methods.

    One of these teachers (called the inspector) sees to it that
    he understands the drawings and instructions for doing the
    work. He teaches him how to do work of the right quality;
    how to make it fine and exact where it should be fine, and
    rough and quick where accuracy is not required,–the one
    being just as important for success as the other. The second
    teacher (the gang boss) shows him how to set up the job in
    his machine, and teaches him to make all of his personal
    motions in the quickest and best way. The third (the speed
    boss) sees that the machine is run at the best speed and

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (50 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    that the proper tool is used in the particular way which will
    enable the machine to finish its product in the shortest
    possible time. In addition to the assistance given by these
    teachers, the workman receives orders and help from four
    other men; from the “repair boss” as to the adjustment,
    cleanliness, and general care of his machine, belting, etc.;
    from the “time clerk,” as to everything relating to his pay
    and to proper written reports and returns; from the “route
    clerk,” as to the order in which he does his work and as to
    the movement of the work from one part of the shop to
    another; and, in case a workman gets into any trouble with
    any of his various bosses, the “disciplinarian” interviews him.

    It must be understood, of course, that all workmen engaged
    on the same kind of work do not require the same amount
    of individual teaching and attention from the functional
    foremen. The men who are new at a given operation
    naturally require far more teaching and watching than those
    who have been a long time at the same kind of jobs.

    Now, when through all of this teaching and this minute
    instruction the work is apparently made so smooth and easy
    for the workman, the first impression is that this all tends to
    make him a mere automaton, a wooden man. As the
    workmen frequently say when they first come under this
    system, “Why, I am not allowed to think or move without
    some one interfering or doing it for me!” The same criticism
    and objection, however, can be raised against all other
    modern subdivision of labor. It does not follow, for example,
    that the modern surgeon is any more narrow or wooden a
    man than the early settler of this country. The frontiersman,
    however, had to be not only a surgeon, but also an
    architect, house-builder, lumberman, farmer, soldier, and
    doctor, and he had to settle his law cases with a gun. You
    would hardly say that the life of the modern surgeon is any
    more narrowing, or that he is more of a wooden man than
    the frontiersman. The many problems to be met and solved
    by the surgeon are just as intricate and difficult and as
    developing and broadening in their way as were those of the
    frontiersman.

    And it should be remembered that the training of the
    surgeon has been almost identical in type with the teaching
    and training which is given to the workman under scientific
    management. The surgeon, all through his early years, is
    under the closest supervision of more experienced men,
    who show him in the minutest way how each element of his
    work is best done. They provide him with the finest
    implements, each one of which has been the subject of
    special study and development, and then insist upon his
    using each of these implements in the very best way. AR of
    this teaching, however, in no way narrows him. On the
    contrary he is quickly given the very best knowledge of his
    predecessors; and, provided (as he is, right from the start)
    with standard implements and methods which represent the
    best knowledge of the world up to date, he is able to use his

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (51 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    own originality and ingenuity to make real additions to the
    world’s knowledge, instead of reinventing things which are
    old. In a similar way the workman who is cooperating with
    his many teachers under scientific management has an
    opportunity to develop which is at least as good as and
    generally better than that which he had when the whole
    problem was “up to him” and he did his work entirely
    unaided.

    If it were true that the workman would develop into a larger
    and finer man without all of this teaching, and without the
    help of the laws which have been formulated for doing his
    particular job, then it would follow that the young man who
    now comes to college to have the help of a teacher in
    mathematics, physics, chemistry, Latin, Greek, etc., would
    do better to study these things unaided and by himself. The
    only difference in the two cases is that students come to
    their teachers, while from the nature of the work done by
    the mechanic under scientific management, the teachers
    must go to him. What really happens is that, with the aid of
    the science which is invariably developed, and through the
    instructions from his teachers, each workman of a given
    intellectual capacity is enabled to do a much higher, more
    interesting, and finally more developing and more profitable
    kind of work than he was before able to do. The laborer who
    before was unable to do anything beyond, perhaps,
    shoveling and wheeling dirt from place to place, or carrying
    the work from one part of the shop to another, is in many
    cases taught to do the more elementary machinist’s work,
    accompanied by the agreeable surroundings and the
    interesting variety and higher wages which go with the
    machinist’s trade. The cheap machinist or helper, who
    before was able to run perhaps merely a drill press, is
    taught to do the more intricate and higher priced lathe and
    planer work, while the highly skilled and more intelligent
    machinists become functional foremen and teachers. And so
    on, right up the line.

    It may seem that with scientific management there is not
    the same incentive for the workman to use his ingenuity in
    devising new and better methods of doing the work, as well
    as in improving his implements, that there is with the old
    type of management. It is true that with scientific
    management the workman is not allowed to use whatever
    implements and methods he sees fit in the daily practice of
    his work. Every encouragement, however, should be given
    him to suggest improvements, both in methods and in
    implements. And whenever a workman proposes an
    improvement, it should be the policy of the management to
    make a careful analysis of the new method, and if
    necessary conduct a series of experiments to determine
    accurately the relative merit of the new suggestion and of
    the old standard. And whenever the new method is found to
    be markedly superior to the old, it should be adopted as the
    standard for the whole establishment. The workman should
    be given the full credit for the improvement, and should be

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (52 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    paid a cash premium as a reward for his ingenuity. In this
    way the true initiative of the workmen is better attained
    under scientific management than under the old individual
    plan.

    The history of the development of scientific, management
    up to date, however, calls for a word of warning. The
    mechanism of management must not be mistaken for its
    essence, or underlying philosophy. Precisely the same
    mechanism will in one case produce disastrous results and
    in another the most beneficent. The same mechanism which
    will produce the finest results when made to serve the
    underlying principles of scientific management, will lead to
    failure and disaster if accompanied by the wrong spirit in
    those who are using it. Hundreds of people have already
    mistaken the mechanism of this system for its essence.
    Messrs. Gantt, Barth and the writer have presented papers
    to, the American Society of Mechanical Engineers on the
    subject of scientific management. In these papers the
    mechanism which is used has been described at some
    length. As elements of this mechanism may be cited:

    Time study, with the implements and methods for properly
    making it.

    Functional or divided foremanship and its superiority to the
    old-fashioned single foreman.

    The standardization of all tools and implements used in the
    trades, and also of the acts or movements of workmen for
    each class of work.

    The desirability of a planning room or department.

    The “exception principle” in management.

    The use of slide-rules and similar timesaving implements.

    Instruction cards for the workman.

    The task idea in management, accompanied by a large
    bonus for the successful performance of the task.

    The “differential rate.”

    Mnemonic systems for classifying manufactured products as
    well as implements used in manufacturing.

    A routing system.

    Modern cost system, etc., etc.

    These are, however, merely the elements or details of the
    mechanism of management. Scientific management, in its

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (53 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    essence, consists of a certain philosophy, which results, as
    before stated, in a combination of the four great underlying
    principles of management:

    First. The development of a true science.
    Second, The scientific selection of the workman.
    Third. His scientific education and development.
    Fourth. Intimate friendly cooperation between the
    management and the men.

    When, however the elements of this mechanism, such as
    time study, functional foremanship etc., are used without
    being accompanied by the true philosophy of management,
    the results are in many cases disastrous. And,
    unfortunately, even when men who are thoroughly in
    sympathy with the principles of scientific management
    undertake to change too rapidly from the old type to the
    new, without heeding the warnings of those who have had
    years of experience in making this change, they frequently
    meet with serious troubles, and sometimes with strikes,
    followed by failure.

    The writer, in his paper on “Shop Management,” has called
    especial attention to the risks which managers run in
    attempting to change rapidly from the old to the new
    management. in many cases, however, this warning has not
    been heeded. The physical changes which are needed, the
    actual time study which has to be made, the standardization
    of all implements connected with the work, the necessity for
    individually studying each machine and placing it in perfect
    order, all take time, but the faster these elements of the
    work are studied and improved, the better for the
    undertaking. On the other hand, the really great problem
    involved in a change from the management of “initiative
    and incentive” to scientific management consists in a
    complete revolution in the mental attitude and the habits of
    all of those engaged in the management, as well of the
    workmen. And this change can be brought about only
    gradually and through the presentation of many object-
    lessons to the workman, which, together with the teaching
    which he receives, thoroughly convince him of the
    superiority of the new over the old way of doing the work.
    This change in the mental attitude of the workman
    imperatively demands time. It is impossible to hurry it
    beyond a certain speed. The writer has over and over again
    warned those who contemplated making this change that it
    was a matter, even in a simple establishment, of from two
    to three years, and that in some cases it requires from four
    to five years.

    The first few changes which affect the workmen should be
    made exceedingly slowly, and only one workman at a time
    should be dealt with at the start. Until this single man has
    been thoroughly convinced that a great gain has come to
    him from the new method, no further change should be
    made. Then one man after another should be tactfully

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (54 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    changed over. After passing the point at which from one.-
    fourth to one-third of the men in the employ of the
    company have been changed from the old to the new, very
    rapid progress can be made, because at about this time
    there is, generally, a complete revolution in the public
    opinion of the whole establishment and practically all of the
    workmen who are working under the old system become
    desirous to share in the benefits which they see have been
    received by those working under the new plan.

    Inasmuch as the writer has personally retired from the
    business of introducing this system of management (that is,
    from all work done in return for any money compensation),
    he does not hesitate again to emphasize the fact that those
    companies are indeed fortunate who can secure the services
    of experts who have had the necessary practical experience
    in introducing scientific management, and who have made a
    special study of its principles. It is not enough that a man
    should have been a manager in an establishment which is
    run under the new principles. The man who undertakes to
    direct the steps to be taken in changing from the old to the
    new (particularly in any establishment doing elaborate
    work) must have had personal experience in overcoming
    the especial difficulties which are always met with, and
    which are peculiar to this period of transition. It is for this
    reason that the writer expects to devote the rest of his life
    chiefly to trying to help those who wish to take up this work
    as their profession, and to advising the managers and
    owners of companies in general as to the steps which they
    should take in making this change.

    As a warning to those who contemplate adopting scientific
    management, the following instance is given. Several men
    who lacked the extended experience which is required to
    change without danger of strikes, or without interference
    with the success of the business, from the management of
    “initiative and incentive” to scientific management,
    attempted rapidly to increase the output in quite an
    elaborate establishment, employing between three
    thousand and four thousand men. Those who undertook to
    make this change were men of unusual ability, and were at
    the same time enthusiasts and I think had the interests of
    the workmen truly at heart. They were, however, warned by
    the writer, before starting, that they must go exceedingly
    slowly, and that the work of making the change in this
    establishment could not be done in less than from three to
    five years. This warning they entirely disregarded. They
    evidently believed that by using much of the mechanism of
    scientific management, in combination with the principles of
    the management of “initiative and incentive,” instead of
    with these principles of scientific management, that they
    could do, in a year or two, what had been proved in the
    past to require at least double this time. The knowledge
    obtained from accurate time study, for example, is a
    powerful implement, and can be used, in one case to
    promote harmony between the workmen and the

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (55 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    management, by gradually educating, training, and leading
    the workmen into new and better methods of doing the
    work, or, in the other case, it may be used more or less as
    a club to drive the workmen into doing a larger day’s work
    for approximately the same pay that they received in the
    past. Unfortunately the men who had charge of this work
    did not take the time and the trouble required to train
    functional foremen, or teachers, who were fitted gradually
    to lead and educate the workmen. They attempted, through
    the old-style foreman, armed with his new weapon
    (accurate time study), to drive the workmen, against their
    wishes, and without much increase in pay, to work much
    harder, instead of gradually teaching and leading them
    toward new methods, and convincing them through object-
    lessons that task management means for them somewhat
    harder work, but also far greater prosperity. The result of all
    this disregard of fundamental principles was a series of
    strikes, followed by the down-fall of the men who attempted
    to make the change, and by a return to conditions
    throughout the establishment far worse than those which
    existed before the effort was made.

    This instance is cited as an object-lesson of the futility of
    using the mechanism of the new management while leaving
    out its essence, and also of trying to shorten a necessarily
    long operation in entire disregard of past experience. It
    should be emphasized that the men who undertook this
    work were both able and earnest, and that failure was not
    due to lack of ability on their part, but to their undertaking
    to do the impossible. These particular men will not again
    make a similar mistake, and it is hoped that their
    experience may act as a warning to others.

    In this connection, however, it is proper to again state that
    during the thirty years that we have been engaged in
    introducing scientific management there has not been a
    single strike from those who were working in accordance
    with its principles, even during the critical period when the
    change was being made from the old to the new. If proper
    methods are used by men who have had experience in this
    work, there is absolutely no danger from strikes or other
    troubles.

    The writer would again insist that in no case should the
    managers of an establishment ‘, the work of which is
    elaborate, undertake to change from the old to the new
    type unless the directors of the company fully understand
    and believe in the fundamental principles of scientific
    management and unless they appreciate all that is involved
    in making this change, particularly the time required, and
    unless they want scientific management greatly.

    Doubtless some of those who are especially interested in
    working men will complain because under scientific
    management the workman, when he is shown how to do
    twice as much work as he formerly did, is not paid twice his

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (56 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    former wages, while others who are more interested in the
    dividends than the workmen will complain that under this
    system the men receive much higher wages than they did
    before.

    It does seem grossly unjust when the bare statement is
    made that the competent pig-iron handler, for instance,
    who has been so trained that he piles 3 6/10 times as much
    iron as the incompetent man formerly did, should receive an
    increase of only 60 per cent in wages.

    It is not fair, however, to form any final judgment until all of
    the elements in the case have been considered. At the first
    glance we see only two parties to the transaction, the
    workmen and their employers. We overlook the third great
    party, the whole people,–the consumers, who buy the
    product of the first two and who ultimately pay both the
    wages of the workmen and the profits of the employers.

    The rights of the people are therefore greater than those of
    either employer or employee. And this third great party
    should be given its proper share of any gain. In fact, a
    glance at industrial history shows that in the end the whole
    people receive the greater part of the benefit coming from
    industrial improvements. In the past hundred years, for
    example, the greatest factor tending toward increasing the
    output, and thereby the prosperity of the civilized world,
    has been the introduction of machinery to replace hand
    labor. And without doubt the greatest gain through this
    change has come to the whole people–the consumer.

    Through short periods, especially in the case of patented
    apparatus, the dividends of those who have introduced new
    machinery have been greatly increased, and in many cases,
    though unfortunately not universally, the employees have
    obtained materially higher wages, shorter hours, and better
    working conditions. But in the end the major part of the
    gain has gone to the whole people.

    And this result will follow the introduction of scientific
    management just as surely as it has the introduction of
    machinery.

    To return to the case of the pig-iron handler. We must
    assume, then, that the larger part of the gain which has
    come from his great increase in output will in the end go to
    the people in the form of cheaper pig-iron. And before
    deciding upon how the balance is to be divided between the
    workmen and the employer, as to what is just and fair
    compensation for the man who does the piling and what
    should be left for the company as profit, we must look at
    the matter from all sides.

    First. As we have before stated, the pig-iron handler is not
    an extraordinary man difficult to find, he is merely a man

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (57 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    more or less of the type of the ox, heavy both mentally and
    physically.

    Second. The work which this man does tires him no more
    than any healthy normal laborer is tired by a proper day’s
    work. (If this man is overtired by his work, then the task
    has been wrongly set and this is as far as possible from the
    object of scientific management.)

    Third. It was not due to this man’s initiative or originality
    that he did his big day’s work, but to the knowledge of the
    science of pig-iron handling developed and taught him by
    some one else.

    Fourth. It is just and fair that men of the same general
    grade (when their all-round capacities are considered)
    should be paid about the same wages when they are all
    working to the best of their abilities. (It would be grossly
    unjust to other laborers, for instance, to pay this man 3
    6/10 as high wages as other men of his general grade
    receive for an honest full day’s work.)

    Fifth. As is explained (page 74), the 60 per cent increase in
    pay which he received was not the result of an arbitrary
    judgment of a foreman or superintendent, it was the result
    of a long series of careful experiments impartially made to
    determine what compensation is really for the man’s true
    and best interest when all things are considered.

    Thus we see that the pig-iron handler with his 60 per cent
    increase in wages is not an object for pity but rather a
    subject for congratulation.

    After all, however, facts are in many cases more convincing
    than opinions or theories, and it is a significant fact that
    those workmen who have come under this system during
    the past thirty years have invariably been satisfied with the
    increase in pay, which they have received, while their
    employers have been equally pleased with their increase in
    dividends.

    The writer is one of those who believes that more and more
    will the third party (the whole people), as it becomes
    acquainted with the true facts, insist that justice shall be
    done to all three parties. It will demand the largest
    efficiency from both employers and employees. It will no
    longer tolerate the type of employer who has his eye on
    dividends alone, who refuses to do his full share of the work
    and who merely cracks his whip over the heads of his
    workmen and attempts to drive them into harder work for
    low pay. No more will it tolerate tyranny on the part of labor
    which demands one increase after another in pay and
    shorter hours while at the same time it becomes less
    instead of more efficient.

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (58 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    And the means which the writer firmly believes will be
    adopted to bring about, first, efficiency both in employer
    and employs and then an equitable division of the profits of
    their joint efforts will be scientific management, which has
    for its sole aim the attainment of justice for all three parties
    through impartial scientific investigation of all the elements
    of the problem. For a time both sides will rebel against this
    advance. The workers will resent any interference with their
    old rule-of-thumb methods, and the management will
    resent being asked to take on new duties and burdens; but
    in the end the people through enlightened public opinion will
    force the new order of things upon both employer and
    employee.

    It will doubtless be claimed that in all that has been said no
    new fact has been brought to light that was not known to
    some one in the past. Very likely this is true. Scientific
    management does not necessarily involve any great
    invention, nor the discovery of new or startling facts. It
    does, however, involve a certain combination of elements
    which have not existed in the past, namely, old knowledge
    so collected, analyzed, grouped, and classified into laws and
    rules that it constitutes a science; accompanied by a
    complete change in the mental attitude of the working men
    as well as of those on the side of the management, toward
    each other, and toward their respective duties and
    responsibilities. Also, a new division of the duties between
    the two sides and intimate, friendly cooperation to an
    extent that is impossible under the philosophy of the old
    management. And even all of this in many cases could not
    exist without the help of mechanisms which have been
    gradually developed.

    It is no single element, but rather this whole combination,
    that constitutes scientific management, which may be
    summarized as:

    Science, not rule of thumb.
    Harmony, not discord.
    Cooperation, not individualism.
    Maximum output, in place of restricted output.
    The development of each man to his greatest efficiency and
    prosperity.

    The writer wishes to again state that: “The time is fast
    going by for the great personal or individual achievement of
    any one man standing alone and without the help of those
    around him. And the time is coming when all great things
    will be done by that type of cooperation in which each man
    performs the function for which he is best suited, each man
    preserves his own individuality and is supreme in his
    particular function, and each man at the same time loses
    none of his originality and proper personal initiative, and yet
    is controlled by and must work harmoniously with many
    other men.”

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (59 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    The examples given above of the increase in output realized
    under the new management fairly represent the gain which
    is possible. They do not represent extraordinary or
    exceptional cases, and have been selected from among
    thousands of similar illustrations which might have been
    given.

    Let us now examine the good which would follow the
    general adoption of
    these principles.

    The larger profit would come to the whole world in general.

    The greatest material gain which those of the present
    generation have over past generations has come from the
    fact that the average man in this generation, with a given
    expenditure of effort, is producing two times, three times,
    even four times as much of those things that are of use to
    man as it was possible for the average man in the past to
    produce. This increase in the productivity of human effort is,
    of course, due to many causes, besides the increase in the
    personal dexterity of the man. It is due to the discovery of
    steam and electricity, to the introduction of machinery, to
    inventions, great and small, and to the progress in science
    and education. But from whatever cause this increase in
    productivity has come, it is to the greater productivity of
    each individual that the whole country owes its greater
    prosperity.

    Those who are afraid that a large increase in the
    productivity of each workman will throw other men out of
    work, should realize that the one element more than any
    other which differentiates civilized from uncivilized
    countries–prosperous from poverty–stricken peoples–is
    that the average man in the one is five or six times as
    productive as the other. It is also a fact that the chief cause
    for the large percentage of the unemployed in England
    (perhaps the most virile nation in the world), is that the
    workmen of England, more than in any other civilized
    country, are deliberately restricting their output because
    they are possessed by the fallacy that it is against their best
    interest for each man to work as hard as he can.

    The general adoption of scientific management would
    readily in the future double the productivity of the average
    man engaged in industrial work. Think of what this means
    to the whole country. Think of the increase, both in the
    necessities and luxuries of life, which becomes available for
    the whole country, of the possibility of shortening the hours
    of labor when this is desirable, and of the increased
    opportunities for education, culture, and recreation which
    this implies. But while the whole world would profit by this
    increase in production, the manufacturer and the workman
    will be far more interested in the especial local gain that
    comes to them and to the people immediately around them.
    Scientific management will mean, for the employers and the

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (60 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

    Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    workmen who adopt it–and particularly for those who adopt
    it first–the elimination of almost all causes for dispute and
    disagreement between them. What constitutes a fair day’s
    work will be a question for scientific investigation, instead of
    a subject to be bargained and haggled over. Soldiering will
    cease because the object for soldiering will no longer exist.
    The great increase in wages which accompanies this type of
    management will largely eliminate the wage question as a
    source of dispute. But more than all other causes, the close,
    intimate cooperation, the constant personal contact
    between the two sides, will tend to diminish friction and
    discontent. It is difficult for two people whose interests are
    the same, and who work side by side in accomplishing the
    same object, all day long, to keep up a quarrel.

    The low cost of production which accompanies a doubling of
    the output will enable the companies who adopt this
    management, particularly those who adopt it first, to
    compete far better than they were able to before, and this
    will so enlarge their markets that their men will have almost
    constant work even in dull times, and that they will earn
    larger profits at all times.

    This means increase in prosperity and diminution in
    poverty, not only for their men but for the whole community
    immediately around them.

    As one of the elements incident to this great gain in output,
    each workman has been systematically trained to his
    highest state of efficiency, and has been taught to do a
    higher class of work than he was able to do under the old
    types of management; and at the same time he has
    acquired a friendly mental attitude toward his employers
    and his whole working conditions, whereas before a
    considerable part of his time was spent in criticism,
    suspicious watchfulness, and sometimes in open warfare.
    This direct gain to all of those working under the system is
    without doubt the most important single element in the
    whole problem.

    Is not the realization of results such as these of far more
    importance than the solution of most of the problems which
    are now agitating both the English and American peoples?
    And is it not the duty of those who are acquainted with
    these facts, to exert themselves to make the whole
    community realize this importance?

    Go to: Introduction Chapter 1 Chapter 2

    file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/SANTOSH/Desktop/Principles%20of%20Scientific%20Management/02.htm (61 of 61)10/25/2006 12:28:35 PM

      intro.htm
      Local Disk
      Introduction

      01.htm
      Local Disk
      Chapter 1: Fundamentals of Scientific Management

      02.htm
      Local Disk
      Chapter 2: The Principles of Scientific Management

    Order your essay today and save 25% with the discount code: STUDYSAVE

    Order a unique copy of this paper

    600 words
    We'll send you the first draft for approval by September 11, 2018 at 10:52 AM
    Total price:
    $26
    Top Academic Writers Ready to Help
    with Your Research Proposal

    Order your essay today and save 25% with the discount code GREEN